Content deleted Content added
Erel Segal (talk | contribs) |
Use "big" delimiters where appropriate and remove unnecessary groups in math markup |
||
(19 intermediate revisions by 16 users not shown) | |||
Line 1:
'''Gorman polar form''' is a
== Motivation ==
Standard [[consumer theory]] is developed for a single consumer. The consumer has a utility function, from which his demand curves can be calculated. Then, it is possible to predict the behavior of the consumer in certain conditions, price or income changes. But in reality, there are many different consumers, each with his own utility function and demand curve. How can we use consumer theory to predict the behavior of an entire society? One option is to represent an entire society as a single "mega consumer", which has an aggregate utility function and aggregate demand curve. But in what cases is it indeed possible to represent an entire society as a single consumer?
Formally:<ref name=Alp>{{cite web | url=http://ocw.mit.edu/courses/economics/14-452-economic-growth-fall-2009/recitations/MIT14_452F09_rec2.pdf | title=Gorman's Aggregation Theorem | date=2009 |
:<math>x^i(p,m^i)</math>
The aggregate demand of society is, in general, a function of the price system and the entire distribution of incomes:
:<math>X(p,m^1,\dots,m^n) = \sum_{i=1}^n
To represent the entire society as a single consumer, the aggregate demand must be a function of only the prices and the ''total'' income, regardless of its distribution:
:<math>X(p,m^1,\dots,m^n) = X\left(p, \sum_{i=1}^n
Under what conditions is it possible to represent the aggregate demand
Early results by Antonelli (1886) and Nataf (1953) had shown that, assuming all individuals face the same prices in a market, their income consumption curves and their [[Engel curve]]s (expenditure as a function of income) should be parallel straight lines. This means that we can calculate an income-consumption curve of an entire society just by summing the curves of the consumers. In other words, suppose the entire society is given a certain income. This income is somehow distributed between the members of society, then each member selects his consumption according to his income-consumption curve. If the curves are all parallel straight lines, the aggregate demand of society will be ''independent of the distribution of income among the agents''.
Line 32:
Two types of preferences that have the Gorman polar form are:<ref name=Varian>{{Cite Varian Microeconomic Analysis 3}}</ref>{{rp|154}}
=== [[Quasilinear utilities]] ===
When the utility function of agent <math>i</math> has the form:
::<math>v(p, m) = v(p)\cdot m</math>▼
::<math>u_i(x, m) = u_i(x) + m</math>
the indirect utility function has (assuming an interior solution) the form:
::<math>v_i(p, m) = v_i(p) + m</math>
Indeed, the Marshallian demand function for the nonlinear good of consumers with quasilinear utilities does not depend on the income at all (in this quasilinear case, the demand for the linear good is linear in income):
2. [[Quasilinear utilities]]. The indirect utility function has the form:▼
::<math>
Hence, the aggregate demand function for the nonlinear good also does not depend on income:
::<math>X(p, M) = \sum_{i=1}^n{(v_i')^{-1}(p)}</math>
The entire society can be represented by a single representative agent with quasilinear utility function:
::<math>U(x, m) = U(x)+m</math>
where the function <math>U</math> satisfies the equality:
::<math>(U')^{-1}(p) = \sum_{i=1}^n{(v_i')^{-1}(p)}</math>
In the special case in which all agents have the same utility function <math>u(x,m)=u(x)+m</math>, the aggregate utility function is:
::<math>U(x,M) = n \cdot u\left(\frac{x}{n}\right) + M</math>
=== [[Homothetic preferences]] ===
▲Both are clearly special cases of the Gorman form.
which is also a special case of the Gorman form.
Particularly: linear, Leontief and Cobb-Douglas utilities are homothetic and thus have the Gorman form.
== Proof of linearity and equality of slope of Engel curves ==
Line 52 ⟶ 69:
== Application ==
Many applications of Gorman polar form are summarized in various texts and in Honohan and Neary's article.<ref>{{cite
== See also ==
Line 60 ⟶ 77:
== References ==
{{Reflist}}
*{{cite book |last=Antonelli |first=G. B. |year=1886 |title=Sulla Teoria Matematica
*{{cite journal |first=W. M. |last=Gorman |title=On a class of preference fields |journal=Metroeconomica |volume=13 |issue=2 |year=1961 |pages=53–56 |doi= 10.1111/j.1467-999X.1961.tb00819.x}}
*{{cite journal |last=
[[Category:Utility function types]]
|