Inverse demand function: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
top: link to demand curve
Just changed those .5 with 1/2, they were creeping me out
 
(11 intermediate revisions by 5 users not shown)
Line 1:
{{Short description|Mathematical function in economics}}
In [[economics]], an '''inverse demand function''' is the [[inversemathematical function]]relationship ofthat expresses price as a [[demandfunction curve(mathematics)|demand function]]. Theof inversequantity demanddemanded function(it viewsis pricetherefore also known as a '''price function of quantity''').<ref>{{Cite book|title=Intermediate microeconomics : with calculus|last=R.|first=Varian, Hal|date = 7 April 2014|isbn=9780393123982|edition= First|___location=New York|pages=115|oclc=884922812}}</ref>
 
Historically, the economists first expressed the price of a good as a function of demand (holding the other economic variables, like income, constant), and plotted the price-demand relationship with demand on the x (horizontal) axis (the [[demand curve]]). Later the additional variables, like prices of other goods, came into analysis, and it became more convenient to express the demand as a [[multivariate function]] (the '''demand function'''):
Quantity demanded, ''Q'', is a function <math>f</math> (the demand function) of price; the inverse demand function treats price as a function of quantity demanded, and is also called the price function:<ref>Samuelson, W and Marks, S Managerial Economics 4th ed. page 35. Wiley 2003.</ref>
<math>{demand} = f({price}, {income}, ...)</math>, so the original demand curve now depicts the ''inverse'' demand function <math>{price} = f^{-1}({demand})</math> with extra variables fixed.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Karaivanov |first1=Alexander |title=The demand function and the demand curve |url=https://www.sfu.ca/~akaraiva/demfun.pdf |website=sfu.ca |publisher=[[Simon Fraser University]] |access-date=29 August 2023}}</ref>
 
:<math>P = f^{-1}(Q).</math>
 
The inverse demand function forms the [[demand curve]] part of the [[Marshallian Scissors]] diagram. The function appears in this form because economists place the independent variable on the y-axis and the dependent variable on the x-axis.
 
==Definition==
 
In mathematical terms, if the [[demand curve|demand function]] is Q<math>{demand} = f(P{price})</math>, then the inverse demand function is P<math>{price} = f<sup>−1^{-1}({demand})</supmath>(Q). The value P inof the inverse demand function is the highest price that could be charged and still generate the quantity demanded Q.<ref>Varian, H.R (2006) Intermediate Microeconomics, Seventh Edition, W.W Norton & Company: London</ref> This is useful because economists typically place price ('''P''') on the vertical axis and quantity ('''demand, Q''') on the horizontal axis in supply-and-demand diagrams, so it is the inverse demand function that depicts the graphed demand curve in the way the reader expects to see.
 
The inverse demand function is the same as the average revenue function, since P = AR.<ref>Chiang & Wainwright, Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics 4th ed. Page 172. McGraw-Hill 2005</ref>
 
To compute the inverse demand function, simply solve for P from the demand function. For example, if the demand function has the form <math>Q = 240 - 2P</math> then the inverse demand function would be <math>P = 120 - .5Q\frac{1}{2}Q</math>.<ref>Samuelson & Marks, Managerial Economics 4th ed. (Wiley 2003)</ref> Note that although price is the dependent variable in the inverse demand function, it is still the case that the equation represents how the price determines the quantity demanded, not the reverse.
 
==Relation to marginal revenue==
Line 23 ⟶ 21:
* The marginal revenue function is below the inverse demand function at every positive quantity.<ref>Perloff, J: Microeconomics Theory & Applications with Calculus page 362. Pearson 2008.</ref>
 
The inverse demand function can be used to derive the total and marginal revenue functions. Total revenue equals price, P, times quantity, Q, or TR = P×Q.
Multiply the inverse demand function by Q to derive the total revenue function: <math>TR = (120 - .5Q\frac{1}{2}Q) ×\cdot Q = 120Q120 Q - 0.5Q²\frac{1}{2}Q^2 </math>.
The marginal revenue function is the first derivative of the total revenue function or MR = 120 - Q. Note that in this linear example the MR function has the same y-intercept as the inverse demand function, the x-intercept of the MR function is one-half the value of the demand function, and the slope of the MR function is twice that of the inverse demand function. This relationship holds true for all linear demand equations. The importance of being able to quickly calculate MR is that the profit-maximizing condition for firms regardless of market structure is to produce where marginal revenue equals marginal cost (MC). To derive MC the first derivative of the total cost function is taken.
 
For example, assume cost, C, equals 420 + 60Q + Q<sup>2</sup>. then MC = 60 + 2Q.<ref>Perloff, Microeconomics, Theory & Applications with Calculus (Pearson 2008) 240.{{ISBN|0-321-27794-5}}</ref> Equating MR to MC and solving for Q gives Q = 20. So 20 is the profit-maximizing quantity: to find the profit-maximizing price simply plug the value of Q into the inverse demand equation and solve for P.
 
==See also==
* [[Supply andHicksian demand function]]
* [[Marshallian demand function]]
*[[Demand]]
* [[Law ofExcess demand function]]
* [[ProfitSupply and (economics)demand]]
* [[Demand]]
* [[Law of demand]]
* [[Profit (economics)]]
 
==References==
{{Reflist}}
 
== Further reading ==
* {{cite book | last1=Ryan | first1=W. J. L. | last2=Pearce | first2=D. W. | title=Price Theory | chapter=Demand Functions | publisher=Macmillan Education UK | publication-place=London | year=1977 | isbn=978-0-333-17913-0 | doi=10.1007/978-1-349-17334-1_2 | pages=31–69}}
 
{{Authority control}}