Content deleted Content added
Crown Prince (talk | contribs) Disambiguated: indifferent → indifference curve |
Link suggestions feature: 2 links added. |
||
(23 intermediate revisions by 20 users not shown) | |||
Line 1:
{{More footnotes|date=February 2010}}
A
Depending on the homogeneity of demand, the lump-sum fee charged varies, but the rational firm will set the per unit charge '''above or equal to''' the [[marginal cost]] of production, and '''below or equal to''' the price the firm would charge in a [[Monopoly#Monopolistic pricing|perfect monopoly]]. Under [[Competition (economics)|competition]] the per-unit price is set below marginal cost.<ref>Hayes, B. (1987), p. 42.</ref>
An important element to remember concerning two-part tariffs
==A two-part tariff when consumer demand is homogeneous==
[[Image:TwoPartTariffHomogDemandNAX.svg|right|thumb|300px|A demonstration of a two-part tariff when demand is homogeneous; the diagram applies for each consumer]]
When consumers have homogeneous demand, any one consumer is representative of the market (the market being n identical consumers). For purposes of demonstration, consider just one consumer who interacts with one firm which experiences
Recall that the [[demand curve]] represents our
If the firm is perfectly competitive, it would charge price Pc and supply Qc to our consumer, making no [[economic profit#Economic definitions of profit|economic profit]] but producing an [[allocative efficiency|allocatively efficient]] output. If the firm is a ''non-price discriminating'' monopolist, it would charge price Pm per unit and supply Qm, maximizing profit but producing below the allocatively efficient level of output Qc. This situation yields economic profit for the firm equal to the green area B, consumer surplus equal to the light blue area A, and a [[deadweight loss]] equal to the purple area C.
If the firm is a ''price discriminating'' monopolist, then it has the capacity to extract more resources from the consumer. It charges a lump sum fee, as well as a per
The lump-sum fee enables the firm to capture all the consumer surplus and deadweight loss areas, resulting in higher profit than a non-price discriminating monopolist could manage. The result is a firm which is in a sense allocatively efficient (price per unit is equal to marginal cost, but total price is not) - one of the redeeming qualities of price discrimination. If there are multiple consumers with homogeneous demand, then profit will equal n times the area ABC, where n is the number of consumers.
Line 46 ⟶ 47:
* landline telephones where there is a fee to use the service ('line rental') and also a fee per call. The line rental covers the cost of providing the service, the per minute charge covers the cost of placing the call on the network.
* [[personal seat license]]s in professional sports, in which fans of a team pay an up-front lump sum fee for the right to purchase tickets at face value
* pay for play games
==Notes==
Line 52 ⟶ 54:
==References==
*{{Cite journal |last=Hayes |first=Beth
*{{cite book
| first = Don E.
Line 59 ⟶ 61:
| title = Microeconomics
| chapter = 12.2 Two-Part Tariffs, Bundling and Tying
| pages = [https://archive.org/details/microeconomics0000wald/page/332 332–335]
| publisher = Pearson Addison Wesley
| isbn = 0-201-65877-1
| chapter-url-access = registration
}}▼
| chapter-url = https://archive.org/details/microeconomics0000wald
| url = https://archive.org/details/microeconomics0000wald/page/332
▲ }}
* Schlereth, C., Stepanchuk, T., Skiera, B. (2010): “Optimization and Analysis of Profitability of Tariff Structures with Different Number of Two-Part Tariffs,” European Journal of Operational Research (EJOR), 206(3), 691-701.
Line 71 ⟶ 76:
[[Category:Pricing]]
|