Content deleted Content added
No edit summary |
m Moving Category:Probability theorems to Category:Theorems in probability theory per Wikipedia:Categories for discussion/Speedy |
||
(41 intermediate revisions by 21 users not shown) | |||
Line 1:
{{Short description|Probability theorem}}
{{Distinguish|text=the [[contraction mapping theorem]]}}
In [[probability theory]], the '''continuous mapping theorem''' states that continuous functions [[Continuous function#Heine definition of continuity|preserve limits]] even if their arguments are sequences of random variables. A continuous function, in [[Continuous function#Heine definition of continuity|Heine's definition]], is such a function that maps convergent sequences into convergent sequences: if ''x<sub>n</sub>'' → ''x'' then ''g''(''x<sub>n</sub>'') → ''g''(''x''). The ''continuous mapping theorem'' states that this will also be true if we replace the deterministic sequence {''x<sub>n</sub>''} with a sequence of random variables {''X<sub>n</sub>''}, and replace the standard notion of convergence of real numbers “→” with one of the types of [[convergence of random variables]].
This theorem was first proved by [[Henry Mann]] and [[Abraham Wald]] in 1943,<ref>{{cite journal | doi = 10.1214/aoms/1177731415 | last1 = Mann |first1=H. B. | last2=Wald |first2=A. | year = 1943 | title = On Stochastic Limit and Order Relationships | journal = [[Annals of Mathematical Statistics]] | volume = 14 | issue = 3 | pages = 217–226 | jstor = 2235800 | doi-access = free }}</ref> and it is therefore sometimes called the '''Mann–Wald theorem'''.<ref>{{cite book | last = Amemiya | first = Takeshi | author-link = Takeshi Amemiya | year = 1985 | title = Advanced Econometrics | publisher = Harvard University Press | ___location = Cambridge, MA | isbn = 0-674-00560-0 | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=0bzGQE14CwEC&pg=pA88 |page=88 }}</ref> Meanwhile, [[Denis Sargan]] refers to it as the '''general transformation theorem'''.<ref>{{cite book |first=Denis |last=Sargan |title=Lectures on Advanced Econometric Theory |___location=Oxford |publisher=Basil Blackwell |year=1988 |isbn=0-631-14956-2 |pages=4–8 }}</ref>
==Statement==
Let {''X<sub>n</sub>''}, ''X'' be [[random element]]s defined on a [[metric space]] ''S''. Suppose a function {{nowrap|''g'': ''S''→''S′''}} (where ''S′'' is another metric space) has the set of [[Discontinuity (mathematics)|discontinuity points]] ''D<sub>g</sub>'' such that {{nowrap|1=Pr[''X'' ∈ ''D<sub>g</sub>''] = 0}}. Then<ref>{{
: <math>
\begin{align}
X_n \ \xrightarrow\text{d}\ X \quad & \Rightarrow\quad g(X_n)\ \xrightarrow\text{d}\ g(X); \\[6pt]
X_n \ \xrightarrow\text{p}\ X \quad & \Rightarrow\quad g(X_n)\ \xrightarrow\text{p}\ g(X); \\[6pt]
X_n \ \xrightarrow{\!\!\text{a.s.}\!\!}\ X \quad & \Rightarrow\quad g(X_n)\ \xrightarrow{\!\!\text{a.s.}\!\!}\ g(X).
\end{align}
</math>
where the superscripts, "d", "p", and "a.s." denote [[convergence in distribution]], [[convergence in probability]], and [[almost sure convergence]] respectively.
==Proof==
<div style="NO-align:right"><small>This proof has been adopted from {{harv|van der Vaart|1998|loc=Theorem 2.3}}</small></div>
Spaces ''S'' and ''S′'' are equipped with certain metrics. For simplicity we will denote both of these metrics using the |
===Convergence in distribution===
We will need a particular statement from the [[portmanteau theorem]]: that convergence in distribution <math>X_n\xrightarrow{d}X</math> is equivalent to
: <math> \
So it suffices to prove that <math> \mathbb E f(g(X_n)) \to \mathbb E f(g(X))</math> for every bounded continuous functional ''f''. For simplicity we assume ''g'' continuous. Note that <math> F = f \circ g</math> is itself a bounded continuous functional. And so the claim follows from the statement above. The general case is slightly more technical.
===Convergence in probability===
Line 57 ⟶ 41:
</math>
On the right-hand side, the first term converges to zero as ''n'' → ∞ for any fixed ''δ'', by the definition of convergence in probability of the sequence {''X<sub>n</sub>''}. The second term converges to zero as ''δ'' → 0, since the set ''B<sub>δ</sub>'' shrinks to an empty set. And the last term is identically equal to zero by assumption of the theorem. Therefore, the conclusion is that
: <math>
\lim_{n\to\infty}\Pr \big(\big|g(X_n)-g(X)\big|>\varepsilon\big) = 0,
Line 63 ⟶ 47:
which means that ''g''(''X<sub>n</sub>'') converges to ''g''(''X'') in probability.
=== Almost sure convergence ===
By definition of the continuity of the function ''g''(·),
: <math>
\lim_{n\to\infty}X_n(\omega) = X(\omega) \quad\Rightarrow\quad \lim_{n\to\infty}g(X_n(\omega)) = g(X(\omega))
</math>
at each point ''X''(''ω'') where ''g''(·) is continuous. Therefore,
: <math>\begin{align}
\
&\geq \
&\geq \
\end{align}</math>
because the intersection of two almost sure events is almost sure.
By definition, we conclude that ''g''(''X<sub>n</sub>'') converges to ''g''(''X'') almost surely.
==See also==
* [[
* [[Portmanteau theorem]]
* [[Pushforward measure]]
==References==
{{reflist}}
[[Category:Theorems in probability theory]]
[[Category:Theorems in statistics]]
[[Category:Articles containing proofs]]
|