Content deleted Content added
Erel Segal (talk | contribs) |
Erel Segal (talk | contribs) |
||
Line 32:
Two types of preferences that have the Gorman polar form are:<ref name=Varian>{{Cite Varian Microeconomic Analysis 3}}</ref>{{rp|154}}
=== [[Quasilinear utilities]] ===
When the utility function of agent <math>i</math> has the form:
::<math>v(p, m) = v(p)\cdot m</math>▼
::<math>u_i(x, m) = u_i(x) + m</math>
::<math>v_i(p, m) = v_i(p) + m</math>
Indeed, the demand functions of consumers with quasilinear utilities do not depend on the income at all:
▲2. [[Quasilinear utilities]]. The indirect utility function has the form:
::<math>
Hence, the aggregate demand function also does not depend on income:
::<math>X(p, M) = \sum_{i=1}^n{(v_i')^{-1}(p)}</math>
The entire society can be represented by a single representative agent with quasilinear utility function:
::<math>U(x, m) = U(x)+m</math>
where the function <math>U</math> satisfies the equality:
::<math>(U')^{-1}(p) = \sum_{i=1}^n{(v_i')^{-1}(p)}</math>
▲Both are clearly special cases of the Gorman form.
=== [[Homothetic preferences]] ===
The indirect utility function has the form:
which is also a special cases of the Gorman form.
Particularly: linear, Leontief and Cobb-Douglas utilities are homothetic and thus have the Gorman form.
== Proof of linearity and equality of slope of Engel curves ==
|