Content deleted Content added
No edit summary |
|||
Line 10:
Several methods are known in the literature for estimating a refined dynamic model as described above. Among these are the Engel and Granger 2-step approach, estimating their ECM in one step and the vector-based VECM using [[Johansen test|Johansen's method]].
===Engel and Granger 2-
The first step of this method is to pretest the individual time series one uses in order to confirm that they are [[Stationary process|non-stationary]] in the first place. This can be done by standard [[unit root]] testing such as [[Augmented Dickey–Fuller test]].
Take the case of two different series <math>x_t</math> and <math>y_t</math>. If both are I(0), standard regression analysis will be valid. If they are integrated of a different order, e.g. one being I(1) and the other being I(0), one has to transform the model.
If they are both integrated to the same order (commonly I(1)), we can estimate an ECM model of the form
''If'' both variables are integrated and this ECM exists, they are cointegrated by the Engle-Granger representation theorem.▼
▲''If'' both variables are integrated and this ECM exists, they are cointegrated by the
The second step is then to estimate the model using [[ordinary least squares]]: <math> y_t = \beta_0 + \beta_1 x_t + \varepsilon_t </math>
If the regression is not spurious as determined by test criteria described above, [[Ordinary least squares]] will not only be valid, but in fact super [[consistent estimator|consistent]] (Stock, 1987).
Then the predicted residuals <math>\hat{\
: <math> A(L) \, \Delta y_t = \gamma + B(L) \, \Delta x_t + \alpha \hat{\ One can then test for cointegration using a standard [[t-statistic]] on <math>\alpha</math>.
While this approach is easy to apply, there are, however numerous problems:
Line 31 ⟶ 37:
===VECM===
The
* Step 1: estimate an unrestricted VAR involving potentially non-stationary variables
Line 38 ⟶ 44:
===An example of ECM===
The idea of cointegration may be demonstrated in a simple macroeconomic setting. Suppose, consumption <math>C_t</math> and disposable income <math>Y_t</math> are macroeconomic time series that are related in the long run (see [[Permanent income hypothesis]]). Specifically, let [[average propensity to consume]] be 90%, that is, in the long run <math>C_t = 0.9 Y_t</math>. From the econometrician's point of view, this long run relationship (aka cointegration) exists if errors from the regression <math>C_t = \beta Y_t+\
In this setting a change <math>\Delta C_t = C_t - C_{t-1}</math> in consumption level can be modelled as <math>\Delta C_t = 0.5 \Delta Y_t - 0.2 (C_{t-1}-0.9 Y_{t-1}) +\
This structure is common to all ECM models. In practice, econometricians often first estimate the cointegration relationship (equation in levels), and then insert it into the main model (equation in differences).
Line 54 ⟶ 60:
*{{cite journal|last1=Phillips|first1=Peter C.B.|title=Understanding Spurious Regressions in Econometrics|journal=Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers 757|date=1985|url=http://cowles.yale.edu/sites/default/files/files/pub/d07/d0757.pdf|publisher=Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University}}
* Sargan, J. D. (1964). "Wages and Prices in the United Kingdom: A Study in Econometric Methodology", 16, 25–54. in ''Econometric Analysis for National Economic Planning'', ed. by P. E. Hart, G. Mills, and J. N. Whittaker. London: Butterworths
*{{cite journal|last1=Yule|first1=Georges Udny|title=Why do we sometimes get nonsense correlations between time series?
[[Category:Error detection and correction]]
|