Convex preferences: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
Add alternative definition and examples
No edit summary
Line 7:
 
== Definition ==
Use ''x'', ''y'', and ''z'' to denote three consumption bundles (combinations of various quantities of various goods). Formally, a preference relation <math>\succeq</math> on the [[consumption set]] ''X'' is called '''convex''' if for any
:<math>x, y, z \in X</math> where <math>y \equivsucceq x </math> and <math>z \succeq x </math>,
 
and for every <math>\theta\in[0,1]</math>:
:<math>\theta y + (1-\theta) xz \succsucceq x </math>.
i.e, for any two bundles that are each viewed as being at least as good as a third bundle, a weighted average of the two bundles is viewed as being at least as good than the third bundle.
:<math>\theta y + (1-\theta) x \succ y </math>.
 
A preference relation <math>\succeq</math> is called ''strictly''strictly convex''' if for any
That is, the preference ordering <math>\succeq</math> is convex if for any two goods bundles that are each viewed as being equivalent, a weighted average of the two bundles is better than each of these bundles.<ref name=Sanders>[http://njsanders.people.wm.edu/100A/Prefs_and_Utility_Examples.pdf Nicholas J. Sanders, "Preference and Utility - Basic Review and Examples"].</ref>
:<math>x, y, z \in X</math> where <math>y \succeq x </math>, <math>z \succeq x </math>, and <math> y \neq z</math>,
 
and for every <math>\theta\in(0,1)</math>:
=== Alternative definition ==
:<math>\theta y + (1-\theta) z \succ x </math>
Use ''x'' and ''y'' to denote two consumption bundles. A preference relation <math>\succeq</math> is called ''convex'' if for any
i.e, for any two distinct bundles that are each viewed as being at least as good as a third bundle, a weighted average of the two bundles (including a positive amount of each bundle) is viewed as being strictly better than the third bundle.
:<math>x, y, z \in X</math> where <math>y \succeq x </math> and <math>z \succeq x </math>,
 
=== Alternative definition ==
Use ''x'' and ''y'' to denote two consumption bundles. A preference relation <math>\succeq</math> is called '''convex''' if for any
:<math>x, y, z \in X</math> where <math>y \succeq x </math> and <math>z \succeq x </math>,
 
and for every <math>\theta\in[0,1]</math>:
:<math>\theta y + (1-\theta) zx \succeq x </math>.
 
That is, if a bundle ''y'' is preferred over a bundle ''x'', then any mix of ''y'' with ''x'' is still preferred over ''x''. <ref name=Board>[http://www.econ.ucla.edu/sboard/teaching/econ11_09/econ11_09_lecture2.pdf Simon Board. "Preferences and Utility]</ref>
== Strict convexity ==
 
A preference relation <math>\succeq</math> is ''strictly'' convex if for any
A preference relation is called '''strictly convex''' if for any
:<math>x, y, z \in X</math> where <math>y \succeq x </math>, <math>z \succeq x </math>, and <math> y \neq z</math>,
:<math>x, y \in X</math> where <math>y \equiv x </math>
 
and for every <math>\theta\in[0,1]</math>:
:<math>\theta y + (1-\theta) zx \succ x </math>.
:<math>\theta y + (1-\theta) x \succ y </math>.
 
Thus the preference ordering <math>\succeq</math>That is strictly convex if, for any two distinct goods bundles that are each viewed as being at least as good as a third bundleequivalent, a weighted average of the two bundles (includingis abetter positivethan amounteach of eachthese bundle)bundles.<ref isname=Sanders>[http://njsanders.people.wm.edu/100A/Prefs_and_Utility_Examples.pdf viewedNicholas asJ. beingSanders, strictly"Preference betterand thanUtility the- thirdBasic bundleReview and Examples"].</ref>
 
== Examples ==
1. If there is only a single commodity type, then any weakly-monotonically-increasing preference relation is convex. This is because, if <math>y \geq x </math> and <math>z \geq x </math>, then every weighted average of ''y'' and ''z'' is also <math>\geq x </math>.
 
2. Consider an economy with two commodity types, 1 and 2. Consider a preference relation represented by the following [[ordinal utility]] function:
:<math>u(x_1,x_2) = x_1 \cdot x_2</math>