Volatility clustering: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
No edit summary
m References from the works of Two Nobel Prize, Granger and Engle, have been added and replace a minor reference
Line 1:
 
In [[finance]], '''volatility clustering''' refers to the observation, first noted as [[Benoît Mandelbrot|Mandelbrot]] (1963), that "large changes tend to be followed by large changes, of either sign, and small changes tend to be followed by small changes."<ref>Mandelbrot, B. B., [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2351623 The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices], The Journal of Business 36, No. 4, (1963), 394-419</ref> A quantitative manifestation of this fact is that, while returns themselves are uncorrelated, absolute returns <math>|r_{t}|</math> or their squares display a positive, significant and slowly decaying autocorrelation function: corr(|r{{sub|t}}|, |r{{sub|t+τ}} |) > 0 for τ ranging from a few minutes to several weeks. This empirical property has been documented in the 90's by [[Clive Granger|Granger]] and Ding (1993)
<ref>Granger, C.W. J., Ding, Z. [http://www.jstor.org/stable/20076016 Some Properties of Absolute Return: An Alternative Measure of Risk ], Annales d'Économie et de Statistique, No. 40 (Oct. - Dec., 1995), pp. 67-91 </ref> and Ding and [[Clive Granger|Granger]] (1996) <ref>Ding, Z., Granger, C.W.J. [https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(95)01737-2 Modeling volatility persistence of speculative returns: A new approach], Journal of Econometrics), 1996, vol. 73, issue 1, 185-215 </ref> among others; see also <ref>{{cite conference|last1=Cont|first1=Rama|date=2007|editor1-last=Teyssière|editor1-first=Gilles|editor2-last=Kirman|editor2-first=Alan|title=Volatility Clustering in Financial Markets: Empirical Facts and Agent-Based Models|url=https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-34625-8_10|conference=|publisher=Springer|volume=|pages=289-309|doi=10.1007/978-3-540-34625-8_10|via=|book-title=Long Memory in Economics}}</ref>. Some studies point further to long-range dependence in volatility time series, see Ding, [[Clive Granger|Granger]] and [[Robert F. Engle|Engle]] (1993) <ref>ContZhuanxin Ding, RamaClive (2005)W.J. "Granger, Robert F. Engle (1993)
[https://doi.org/10.10071016/10927-84628-0485398(93)90006-6_11D LongA rangelong dependencememory inproperty financialof markets]".stock Inmarket Lévy-Véhelreturns J.and a new model], LuttonJournal E.of (eds)Empirical FractalsFinance,
Volume in1, Engineering.Issue Springer1, London.1993, pp.Pages 159–179.83-106</ref> and Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard<ref> {{cite encyclopedia |author= Ole E. Barndorff-Nielsen, Neil Shephard|title= Volatility|encyclopedia= Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance|date= October 2010 |year= 2010 |publisher= Wiley|editor-last= Cont|editor-first=Rama |doi=10.1002/9780470061602.eqf19019 }}
</ref>.
 
Observations of this type in financial time series go against simple random walk models and have led to the use of [[GARCH]] models and mean-reverting [[stochastic volatility]] models in financial forecasting and [[Derivative (finance)|derivatives]] pricing. The [[ARCH]] ([[Robert F. Engle|Engle]], 1982) and [[GARCH]] ([[Tim Bollerslev|Bollerslev]], 1986) models aim to more accurately describe the phenomenon of volatility clustering and related effects such as [[kurtosis]]. The main idea behind these two models is that volatility is dependent upon past realizations of the asset process and related volatility process. This is a more precise formulation of the intuition that asset [[Volatility (finance)|volatility]] tends to revert to some mean rather than remaining constant or moving in [[monotonic]] fashion over time.