Dynamic unobserved effects model: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
m top: clean up, typo(s) fixed: … → ... (2), doesn’t → doesn't, one’s → one's (4)
add lead, copyedit
Line 1:
{{Short description|Statistical model used in econometrics}}
{{Multiple issues|
{{Technical|date=January 2018}}
{{Cleanup reorganize|date=January 2018}}
{{lead missing|date=November 2015}}
}}
 
A '''dynamic unobserved effects model''' is a [[statistical model]] used in [[econometrics]]. It is characterized by the influence of previous values of the [[dependent variable]] on its present value, and by the presence of unobservable [[explanatory variable]]s.
The “dynamic” here means the dependence of the dependent variable on its past history, this is usually used to model the “state dependence” in economics. For instance, a person who cannot find a job this year, it will be hard for her to find a job next year because the fact that she doesn't have a job this year will be a very negative signal for the potential employers. The “unobserved effects” means that one or some of the explanatory variables are unobservable. For example, one's preference affects quite a lot her consumption choice of the ice cream with a certain taste, but preference is unobservable. A typical dynamic unobserved effects model is represented <ref>Wooldridge, J. (2002): Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 495.</ref> as:
 
The term “dynamic” here means the dependence of the dependent variable on its past history,; this is usually used to model the “state dependence” in economics. For instance, for a person who cannot find a job this year, it will be hard for herharder to find a job next year because theher factpresent thatlack she doesn't haveof a job this year will be a very negative signal for the potential employers. The “unobserved“Unobserved effects” means that one or some of the explanatory variables are unobservable.: Forfor example, one'sconsumption preferencechoice affectsof quiteone a lot her consumption choiceflavor of the ice cream withover a certain taste, but preferenceanother is unobservable.a A typical dynamic unobserved effects model is represented <ref>Wooldridge, J. (2002): Econometric Analysisfunction of Crosspersonal Section and Panel Datapreference, MITbut Press,preference Cambridge,is Mass, pp 495unobservable.</ref> as:
 
==Formulation==
A typical dynamic unobserved effects model is represented<ref>Wooldridge, J. (2002): Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 495.</ref> as:
 
P(y<sub>it</sub> = 1│y<sub>i,t-1</sub>, ... , y<sub>i,0</sub> , z<sub>i</sub> , c<sub>i</sub> ) = G (z<sub>it</sub> δ + ρ y<sub>i,t-1</sub> + c<sub>i</sub>)
 
where c<sub>i</sub> is an unobservable explanatory variable, z<sub>it</sub> isare explanatory variables which are exogenous conditional on the c<sub>i</sub>, and G(∙) is a [[cumulative distribution function]].
 
==Estimates of parameters==
In this type of model, economists have a special interest in ρ, which is used to characterize the state dependence. For example, ''y<sub>i,t</sub>'' can be a woman's choice whether to work or not, ''z<sub>it</sub>'' includes the ''i''-th individual's age, education level, numbersnumber of kidschildren, and soother onfactors. ''c<sub>i</sub>'' can be some individual specific characteristic which cannot be observed by economists.<ref>James J. Heckman (1981): Studies in Labor Markets, University of Chicago Press, Chapter Heterogeneity and State Dependence</ref> It is a reasonable conjecture that one's labor choice in period ''t'' should depend on his or her choice in period ''t''&nbsp;&minus;&nbsp;1 due to habit formation or other reasons. This is dependence is characterized by parameter ''ρ''.
 
There are several [[Maximum likelihood|MLE]]-based approaches to estimate ''δ'' and ''ρ'' consistently. The simplest way is to treat ''y<sub>i,0</sub>'' as non-stochastic and assume ''c<sub>i</sub>'' is [[Independent variable#Use in statistics|independent]] with ''z<sub>i</sub>''. Then integrateby integrating ''P(y<sub>i,t</sub> , y<sub>i,t-1</sub> , … , y<sub>i,1</sub> | y<sub>i,0</sub> , z<sub>i</sub> , c<sub>i</sub>)'' against the density of ''c<sub>i</sub>'', we can obtain the conditional density P(y<sub>i,t</sub> , y<sub>i,t-1</sub> , ... , y<sub>i,1</sub> |y<sub>i,0</sub> , z<sub>i</sub>). The objective function for the conditional MLE can be represented as: ''<math> \sum_{i=1}^N </math> log (P (y<sub>i,t</sub> , y<sub>i,t-1</sub>, … , y<sub>i,1</sub> | y<sub>i,0</sub> , z<sub>i</sub>)).''
 
Treating ''y<sub>i,0</sub>'' as non-stochastic implicitly assumes the independence of ''y<sub>i,0</sub>'' on ''z<sub>i</sub>''. But in most of the cases in reality, ''y<sub>i,0</sub>'' depends on ''c<sub>i</sub>'' and ''c<sub>i</sub>'' also depends on ''z<sub>i</sub>''. An improvement on the approach above is to assume a density of ''y<sub>i,0</sub>'' conditional on (''c<sub>i</sub>, z<sub>i</sub>'') and conditional likelihood ''P(y<sub>i,t</sub> , y<sub>i,t-1</sub> , … , y<sub>t,1</sub>,y<sub>i,0</sub> | c<sub>i</sub>, z<sub>i</sub>)'' can be obtained. IntegrateBy integrating this likelihood against the density of ''c<sub>i</sub>'' conditional on ''z<sub>i</sub>'' and, we can obtain the conditional density ''P(y<sub>i,t</sub> , y<sub>i,t-1</sub> , … , y<sub>i,1</sub> , y<sub>i,0</sub> | z<sub>i</sub>)''. The objective function for the [[conditional MLE]] <ref>Greene, W. H. (2003), Econometric Analysis , Prentice Hall , Upper Saddle River, NJ .</ref> is ''<math> \sum_{i=1}^N </math> log (P (y<sub>i,t</sub> , y<sub>i,t-1</sub>, … , y<sub>i,1</sub> | y<sub>i,0</sub> , z<sub>i</sub>)).''
 
Based on the estimates for (''δ, ρ'') and the corresponding variance, testvalues aboutof the coefficients can be implemented tested<ref>Whitney K. Newey, Daniel McFadden, Chapter 36 Large sample estimation and hypothesis testing, In: Robert F. Engle and Daniel L. McFadden, Editor(s), Handbook of Econometrics, Elsevier, 1994, Volume 4, Pages 2111–2245, {{ISSN|1573-4412}}, {{ISBN|9780444887665}},</ref> and the average partial effect can be calculated.<ref>Chamberlain, G. (1980), “Analysis of Covariance with Qualitative Data,” Journal of Econometrics 18, 5–46</ref>
 
==References==