Investment-specific technological progress: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
Attempted to restructure the Importance section (relabeled significance) as per Wikipedia guidelines to remove the essay-like attribute of the article.
Updated all refrences to regular citation format. Formated the document to remove essay like status.
Line 13:
 
Technological progress has direct positive impacts upon human [[welfare economics|welfare]]. As a result of new technologies producers can produce a greater volume of product at a lower cost. The resulting reduction in prices benefits the consumer, who now can purchase more. <ref>{{Citation | last=Greenwood | first=Jeremy | last2=Vandenbroucke | first2=Guillaume | year=2006 | chapter= Hours Worked: Long-Run Trends
| editor=Lawrence E. Blume, Steven N. Durlauf | title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics | edition=2nd | publisher=Palgrave Macmillan | place=London }}</ref>. Women have been able to break away from the traditional "[[housewife]]" role, join the labor-force in greater numbers (Greenwood et al. 2005) and become less economically dependent on men (<ref>{{Citation | last=Greenwood &| first=Jeremy | last2=Guner | first2=Nezih | title=Marriage and Divorce since World War II: Analyzing the Role of Technological Progress on the Formation of Households | journal=NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2008| volume=23 |year=2009)| pages=231–276 | doi=10.1086/593087| url=https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/35115/1/559459432.pdf}}</ref>. Further impacts include a reduction in [[child labor]] starting around 1900 <ref>{{Citation| last=Greenwood | first=Jeremy | last2=Seshadri | first2=Ananth| year=2005 | chapter=Technological Progress and Economic Transformation | editor= Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf | title=Handbook of Economic Growth | publisher=Elsevier North-Holland | place=Amsterdam}}.</ref>.
 
[[Image:kid1.jpg|thumb|400px|center|Figure 1]]
 
==A simple example: the microwave oven==
An example of investment-specific technological progress is the [[microwave oven]]. The first microwave oven cost between $2000 and $3000 US and was housed in refrigerator-sized cabinets. Through regular technological investment the microwave industry has developed into a competitive market, with small compact units in many households <ref> {{Citation
An example of investment-specific technological progress is the [[microwave oven]]. The idea of the microwave came to be by accident: in 1946 an engineer noticed that a [[candy bar]] in his pocket had melted while working on something completely unrelated to cooking (Gallawa 2005). The development of this good, from melting the candy bar to the home appliance known today, took time and the investment of resources to make a microwave small and cheap. The first microwave oven cost between 2000 and 3000 dollars and was housed in refrigerator-sized cabinets (Gallawa 2005)! Today, almost any college student can enjoy a 3-minute microwaveable meal in the smallest dorm room. But a microwave's uses do not stop at the dorm room. Many industries have found microwave heating advantageous: it has been used to dry cork, ceramics, paper, leather, and so on (Gallawa 2005). However, for either college students or firms to reap the benefits of quick warming, they must first "invest" in a microwave oven (that "embodies" the technological advance). To realize the benefits of investment-specific technological progress you must first invest in a technology that embodies it.
| last=Gallawa | first=J. Carlton | title=Who Invented Microwaves | url= http://www.gallawa.com/microtech/history.html| year=2005}}</ref>. Many industries have adopted the microwave through capital or research investment, applications outside the food industry include the [[iron]] and [[steel]] industry as a heating tool<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Yoshikawa|first=Noboru|last2=Ishizuka|first2=Etsuko|last3=Mashiko|first3=Kenichi|last4=Chen|first4=Yan|last5=Taniguchi|first5=Shoji|date=2007|title=Brief Review on Microwave (MW) Heating, Its Application to Iron & Steel Industry and to the Relevant Environmental Techniques|url=http://joi.jlc.jst.go.jp/JST.JSTAGE/isijinternational/47.523?from=CrossRef|journal=ISIJ International|language=en|volume=47|issue=4|pages=523–527|doi=10.2355/isijinternational.47.523|issn=0915-1559}}</ref> and the [[chemical industry]] as a tool for [[organic synthesis]]<ref>{{Cite book|url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/945552571|title=Milestones in microwave chemistry|others=Keglevich, György,|isbn=978-3-319-30632-2|___location=Switzerland|oclc=945552571}}</ref>.
 
==Measurement==
WhileThere is no direct metric for measuring technological progress, isas notsuch easy,workarounds economistsbased haveupon founddirect indirectrelationships waysbetween oftechnological estimatingprogress it.and Ifrecordable values are used. "'investmentInvestment-specific'" technological progress makes producing goods easier, then the price of the goods affectedas (relativea toresult the price of otherthe goods) shouldwill decrease. In particular, "investment-specific" technological advance has affected the prices of two inputs into the production process: equipment and structures. Think of equipment as machines (like computers) and structures as buildings. If there is technological progress in the production (or creation) of these goods, then oneit wouldis expectexpected the price of them towill fall or the value of themthe good towill rise relative to older versions of the same good.
 
Figure 2 (the pink line) shows how the price of new [[Durable good|producer durables]] (such as equipment) in the United States relative to the price of new consumer nondurables (like clothing) has consistently declined over the past fifty years (<ref>{{Citation | last=Gort et| al.first=Michael | last2=Greenwood | first2=Jeremy | last3=Rupert | first3=Peter | title=How Much of Economic Growth is Fueled by Investment-Specific Technological Change? | journal=Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland | date=March 1, 1999) }} </ref>. To calculate the relative price of producer durables divide the price that firms pay (for the durable inputs of production) by the price that a regular consumer paysof (forthe thingsfirms likeproduct [[jeans]])pays. People use relativeRelative prices soare theyused canto sayrepresent how many units of equipment can be bought instead (or in terms) of buyingthe onea single unit of consumer goods.As Figurea 3result (theof pink line) says that overtechnological timedevelopment, firms have been able to buy more andcomparitevly more units of equipment insteadfor of oneeach unit of consumption, especially when taken into account that the quality of equipment being acquired has increased (a computer today is much faster than a computer five years ago and that should be taken into account when comparing their prices). When changes in quality are not taken into account (which is wrong) it looks like the price of equipment has not decreased as much (see the black line in Figure 2).
with the quality of the goods increasing while the cost of production decreases. When changes in quality are not taken into account the apparent price of equipment undergoes a smaller reduction (see the black line in Figure 2).
 
[[File:Investment-specific technological progress - Figure 2.jpg|thumb|400px|center|Figure 2]]
 
MeasuringOne approach to measuring the price of technologicaly improved structures is moreto complicatedassign thannewer measuringbuilding thea pricehigher ofvalue equipment,due butto economiststhe haveembodyment againof beenthe ablenew totechnology getwith anthe ideadesign of<ref>{{Citation how much| progresslast=Gort there| hasfirst=Michael been| inlast2=Greenwood structures| (suchfirst2=Jeremy as buildings).| Onelast3=Rupert approach| isfirst3=Peter that if| newertitle=How buildingsMuch wereof constructedEconomic orGrowth designedis usingFueled newerby technologiesInvestment-Specific thenTechnological theyChange? should be| worthjournal=Economic moreCommentary, thanFederal olderReserve buildingsBank (becauseof theyCleveland '''embody'''| thedate=March new1, technology1999 (Gort}} et al. 1999)</ref>. In particular, they should rent for more. As Figure 3 shows, this is truei.e. Rentingrenting a square foot in a new building is much more expensive than renting a square foot in a building forty years old. So it must be the case that you are paying for a nicer, more functional and maybe even safer building.
 
[[Image:figure4.jpg|thumb|400px|center|Figure 3]]
Figures 2 and 3 suggest that '''investment-specific''' technological change is operating in the US. The annual rate of technological progress in equipment and structures has been estimated to be about 3.2% and 1%, respectively (Gort<ref>{{Citation et al.| 1999) (last=Greenwood et| al.first=Jeremy | last2=Hercowitz | first2=Zvi | last3=Krusell | first3=Per |authorlink3=Per Krusell | title=Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change | journal= American Economic Review | volume=87 | issue=3 | year=1997) | pages=342–362}} </ref>.
 
==Conclusion==
In the second section it was mentioned that "investment-specific" technological change is important since it will affect production (both in quality and size). An important question then is, just how much "bang for your buck" do you get with "investment-specific" technological change? The answer is quite astounding; economists have found that 37% of growth in United States output (production) is due to technological progress in equipment and 15% is due to technological progress in structures (Gort et al. 1999) (Greenwood et al. 1997). All in all, more than half (37% + 15% = 52%) of the growth of the United States economy is due to "investment-specific" technological change (Gort et al. 1999) (Greenwood et al. 1997).
 
==References==
* {{Citation
| last=Gallawa | first=J. Carlton
| title=Who Invented Microwaves
| url= http://www.gallawa.com/microtech/history.html| year=2005}}.
* {{Citation
| last=Gort | first=Michael | last2=Greenwood | first2=Jeremy
| last3=Rupert | first3=Peter
| title=How Much of Economic Growth is Fueled by Investment-Specific Technological Change?
| journal=Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland | date=March 1, 1999 }}.
* {{Citation
| last=Greenwood | first=Jeremy | last2=Guner | first2=Nezih
| title=Marriage and Divorce since World War II: Analyzing the Role of Technological Progress on the Formation of Households
| journal=NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2008| volume=23 |year=2009| pages=231–276 | doi=10.1086/593087| url=https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/35115/1/559459432.pdf}}.
* {{Citation
| last=Greenwood | first=Jeremy | last2=Hercowitz | first2=Zvi
| last3=Krusell | first3=Per |authorlink3=Per Krusell
| title=Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change
| journal= American Economic Review | volume=87 | issue=3
| year=1997 | pages=342–362}}.
* {{Citation
| last=Greenwood | first=Jeremy
| last2=Jovanovic | first2=Boyan | authorlink2=Boyan Jovanovic
| year=2001 | chapter=Accounting for Growth
| editor=Charles R. Hulten, Edwin R. Dean & Michael J. Harper
| title=New Developments in Productivity Analysis | publisher=University of Chicago Press | place=Chicago }}.
* {{Citation
| last=Greenwood | first=Jeremy | last2=Seshadri | first2=Ananth
| last3=Yorukoglu | first3=Mehmet
| title=Engines of Liberation
| journal= Review of Economic Studies | volume=72
| issue=1 | year=2005 | pages=109–133
| doi=10.1111/0034-6527.00326 }}.
* {{Citation
| last=Lebergott | first=Stanley
| title=Manpower in Economic growth: The American Record since 1800
| year=1964 | publisher=McGraw-Hill Company | place=New York}}.
 
[[Category:Economic growth]]