Late capitalism

(Redirected from Fall of Capitalism)

The concept of late capitalism (in German: Spätkapitalismus, sometimes also translated as "late stage capitalism"[1]), was first used in 1925 by the German social scientist Werner Sombart (1863–1941)[2] to describe the new capitalist order emerging out of World War I. Sombart claimed that it was the beginning of a new stage in the history of capitalism.[3] His vision of the emergence, rise and decline of capitalism was influenced by Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels’s interpretation of human history in terms of a sequence of different economic modes of production, each with a historically limited lifespan.[4]

Werner Sombart as a young scholar, before World War 1

As a young man, Sombart was a socialist who associated with Marxist intellectuals and the German social-democratic party. Friedrich Engels praised Sombart’s review of the first edition of Marx’s Capital Vol. 3 in 1894, and sent him a letter.[5] As a mature academic who became well known for his own sociological writings, Sombart had a sympathetically critical attitude to the ideas of Karl Marx — seeking to criticize, modify and elaborate Marx's insights, while disavowing Marxist doctrinairism and dogmatism.[6] This prompted a critique from Friedrich Pollock, a founder of the Frankfurt School at the Institute for Social Research.[7] Sombart's clearly written texts and lectures helped to make "capitalism" a household word in Europe, as the name of a socioeconomic system with a specific structure and dynamic, a history, a mentality, a dominant morality and a culture.[8]

Different modern uses

edit

The use of the term "late capitalism" to describe the nature of the modern epoch existed for four decades in continental Europe, before it began to be used by academics and journalists in the English-speaking world — via English translations of German-language Critical Theory texts, and especially via Ernest Mandel's 1972 book Late Capitalism, published in English in 1975.[9] Mandel's new theory of late capitalism was unrelated to Sombart's theory, and Sombart is not mentioned at all in Mandel's book. For many Western Marxist scholars since that time, the historical epoch of late capitalism starts with the outbreak (or the end[10]) of World War II (1939–1945), and includes the post–World War II economic expansion, the world recession of the 1970s and early 1980s, the era of neoliberalism and globalization, the 2008 financial crisis and the aftermath in a multipolar world society. Particularly in the 1970s and 1980s, many economic and political analyses of late capitalism were published. From the 1990s onward, the academic analyses focused more on the culture, sociology and psychology of late capitalism.[11]

According to Google Books Ngram Viewer, the frequency of mentions per year of the term "late capitalism" in publications has steadily increased since the 1960s. Sociologist David Inglis states that “Various species of non-Marxist theorizing have borrowed or appropriated the general notion of historical ‘lateness’ from the original Marxist conception of ‘late capitalism’, and they have applied it to what they take to be the current form of ‘modernity’.”[12] This leads to the idea of late modernity as a new phase in modern society. In recent years, there is also a revival of the concept of "late capitalism" in popular culture, but with a meaning that is different from previous generations. In 2017, an article in The Atlantic highlighted that the term "late capitalism" was again in vogue in America as an ironic term for modern business culture.[13]

In 2024, a Wall Street Journal writer complained that “Our universities teach that we are living in the End Times of ‘late capitalism.’”[14] Chine McDonald, the director of the British media-massaging thinktank Theos argues that the reason why so many people these days are preoccupied with the “end times”, is because “doom sells”: it caters to deep psychological needs that sell a lot of books, movies and TV series with apocalyptic themes.[15]

In contemporary academic or journalistic usage, "late stage capitalism" often refers to a new mix of (1) the strong growth of the digital, electronics and military industries as well as their influence in society, (2) the economic concentration of corporations and banks, which control gigantic assets and market shares internationally (3) the transition from Fordist mass production in huge assembly-line factories to Post-Fordist automated production and networks of smaller, more flexible manufacturing units supplying specialized markets, (4) increasing economic inequality of income, wealth and consumption, and (5) consumerism on credit and the increasing indebtedness of the population.[16]

Skepticism about late capitalism

edit

The idea of "late capitalism" was never accepted by the majority of social scientists, economists and historians, for five kinds of reasons:

It was considered that the expression was tinged with illiberal political biases about capitalism, and/or because it is unknowable or uncertain whether capitalism is "on its last legs", or "if and when it will end". The German-American economist Hans Philip Neisser, a lecturer at the New School of Social Research, stated in 1954 that "The vital power of all civilizations and all economic systems some day declines and comes to an end. At what point will the free enterprise system definitely reach its old age? I do not know of any scientific way to determine this moment in advance.”[17] The unresolved questions were: "late" in what sense? In comparison to what? How do we know? What could possibly replace capitalism? The liberal economist Paul Krugman stated in 2018 that "I’ve had several interviews lately in which I was asked whether capitalism had reached a dead end, and needed to be replaced with something else. I'm never sure what the interviewers have in mind; neither, I suspect, do they."[18]

 
Paul Krugman, winner of the Nobel Prize in Economics, 7 September 2008

Admittedly there have been very severe "systemic" capitalist crises in the past. During the Great Depression, for example, real GNP in the United States fell by 9.9% in 1930, 7.7% in 1931, and 14.8% in 1932. In 1931, federal tax receipts were roughly half their 1929 level. In 1932, industrial production in Germany and the United States was 47% below their 1929 level – the value of net output was roughly halved. In the United States, net investment turned negative, unemployment rose to a quarter of the labour force, and in 1933, the country suffered the most severe banking crisis ever experienced in peacetime.[19] However, the economy did recover to "business as usual" eventually, and new economic growth was achieved (in some parts of the world, such as in the Eastern Bloc countries, the existing state power was overthrown, and the local business class was largely ousted or eradicated for many years).

Theories of "late capitalism" or the "decline of capitalism" failed to explain events like (1) the long economic boom from 1947 until 1973, (2) the global resurgence of competitive market capitalism from the mid-1980s (the era of neoliberalism, globalization, the Asian Tigers and the Brics), (3) the collapse of state socialism in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe in 1989–91 and (4) the rapid growth of state capitalism in the Russian Federation, the People's Republic of China and the Republic of India. If capitalism is really declining or on the road to collapse, what actually happened so far is contrary to what we would expect.

According to skeptics of the "late capitalism" idea, so far there just has not been any real evidence of: (1) long-term economic stagnation or prolonged negative economic growth in the advanced capitalist countries; (2) pervasive social decay and persistent cultural degeneration that just keeps getting worse and worse, and (3) pervasive and persistent rejection of capitalism and business culture by the majority of the population[20] (admittedly, deep and prolonged crises did occur in some lower-income countries, and some countries appear to be stuck long-term in terrible poverty). It is argued that most of the time, in most places in the world, economic growth was either slower than the average, or faster than the average. Prolonged zero economic growth or negative growth (for more than a few years) has been rare. When it is argued that capitalist economic growth has persistently been sub-optimal, there is no agreement about what optimal growth would look like, and how it would be achieved.

Critics of the skepticism about “late capitalism” will admit that there has been growth in the first quarter of the 21st century. However, they argue that this growth has been very uneven. It involves mainly the top quintile of the world population, plus a group of newly industrializing countries, which includes most importantly the economic growth of the People’s Republic of China, with a population of 1.4 billion. This tilts the “grand averages” of the distribution of global wealth and income considerably. Simply put, if workers in many low-income countries and regions can now earn a few extra dollars per day, this just does not change their total life situation very much. In 2001, for example, Ankie Hoogvelt stated:

“The Human Development Report 1999 notes that between 1980 and 1996, gross national product (GNP) per capita declined in no less than fifty-nine countries. It reports that the income gap between the fifth of the world’s population living in the richest countries, and the fifth in the poorest, widened from 30 to 1 in 1960 to 74 to 1 in 1997, and that income disparities increased in many countries, including the rich, during the 1980s and the 1990s. (…) the rising fortunes of new regions and groups of countries in the world economy, and the decline of others, should not blind us to the way that wealth and poverty are connected.”[21]

The Human Development Report 2019 shows what (still rising) economic inequality actually means.[22] So the reply to the skeptics is that capitalism can still make life better for a part of the world population, but not for all – the majority of the world population do not benefit very much from it, or get no benefit from it. If we focus only on well-off people in the advanced (or advancing) capitalist countries, we only get a part of the total picture.

Intellectual history of the idea

edit

Marxist precursors

edit

Ever since the famous theoretical controversy between orthodox Marxists and revisionists in the 1890s, socialists have been discussing the decline, breakdown and collapse of bourgeois society.[23] There were many attempts at theoretical and mathematical proofs of the decline and collapse of capitalism. There were also attempts to create a perspective on the nature of the epoch and the future of society, to guide political action.[24]

 
Vladimir Lenin, July 1920

The Russian revolutionary Vladimir Lenin famously declared in 1920 that there are no "absolutely hopeless situations" for capitalism; unless an anti-capitalist political revolution overthrows the rule of the bourgeoisie, the capitalist system can always recover sooner or later.[25] Lenin considered that the fate of capitalism was essentially a political issue: it depended on the outcome of class struggles. The leaders of the Communist International (founded in 1919) believed that with the First World War, a new world epoch of wars and revolutions had begun[26] — the epoch of capitalist decline.[27] The Comintern programme defined imperialism as the highest and final stage of capitalism.[28] According to Lenin,

“More and more prominently there emerges, as one of the tendencies of imperialism, the creation of the “rentier state”, the usurer state, in which the bourgeoisie to an ever-increasing degree lives on the proceeds of capital exports and by “clipping coupons”. It would be a mistake to believe that this tendency to decay precludes the rapid growth of capitalism. It does not. In the epoch of imperialism, certain branches of industry, certain strata of the bourgeoisie and certain countries betray, to a greater or lesser degree, now one and now another of these tendencies. On the whole, capitalism is growing far more rapidly than before; but this growth is not only becoming more and more uneven in general, its unevenness also manifests itself, in particular, in the decay of the countries which are richest in capital (Britain).”[29]

The term "late capitalism" was generally not used by Marxist-Leninists. They used the concept of state monopoly capitalism (originally formulated by Lenin) to denote the highest developmental stage of capitalism.[30] Many non-Marxist historians and sociologists, however, have preferred more neutral terms, such as the "late modern era"[31] or "post-modern era". Some Continental and Anglo-Saxon historians refer to late bourgeois society, in contrast to early bourgeois society in the 17th and 18th century and classical bourgeois society in the 19th and early 20th century.

Sombart's influence and legacy

edit

The term "late capitalism" was first defined by the German social scientist Werner Sombart in a 1925 reference article about the characteristics and development of capitalism[32] and in the third volume of Der Moderne Kapitalismus (completed in 1926, published in 1927). The term also occurs in a 1928 publication of Sombart's text for a lecture on transformations in capitalism.[33] Only the first volume of Sombart's three-volume Modern capitalism - a very influential work in its time - has been translated into English so far.[34] A comprehensive English introduction to Modern capitalism was published in 1933.[35] Sombart divided the history of capitalism into four main stages of development:[36]

 
Prof. Werner Sombart, at the height of his academic career
  • Pre-capitalist economy (vorkapitalistische Wirtschaft) from the early Middle Ages up to 1500 AD, the subject of the first volume of Modern capitalism (in two parts, published in 1902/1903, with four more editions in 1913-1941).
  • Early capitalism (Frühkapitalismus) from the 1500s to 1760, dealt with in the second volume (in two parts, published in 1906/1907, with another edition in 1913 and 1928).
  • Advanced capitalism (Hochkapitalismus) from 1760 to the beginning of World War I in 1914, the subject of the third volume (in two parts, published in 1927, with another edition in 1932 and 1941).
  • Late capitalism (Spätkapitalismus) since then, referred to sporadically in the third volume[37] and discussed in a few lectures and articles.[38]

In the introduction to the third volume of Modern capitalism, Sombart remarks that he considered it one of his (modest) achievements, that his concepts of “early capitalism, high capitalism, late capitalism” had become “commonly known" in scientific circles, and were accepted in ordinary language.[39] In the last parts of the third volume of Modern Capitalism,[40] Sombart discussed recent new developments in different sectors of the capitalist economy (which Marx apparently had not foreseen), and he speculated about economic life in the future. But he remained cautious, and was reluctant to venture bold predictions (in later editions of the volumes of Modern capitalism, he introduced revisions and alterations). Broadly speaking, he viewed late capitalism as an epoch of relative economic stagnation, characterized by bureaucratic regulation, some nationalized industries, and indicative macroeconomic planning.

For Sombart, the visible signs of the end of high capitalism in the last years before 1914 included the end of the "purely naturalistic mode of existence of capitalism with normative ideas"; the dethronement of the pursuit of profit as the sole determining factor of economic behavior; the decline of economic dynamism and risktaking in economic development; the shift from free competition to industrial cartels; and the statutory corporatization of enterprises.[41]

In his approach, Sombart emphasized, it is always the “capitalist spirit” that shapes the historical epoch, including the economic era. A new epoch begins, when the capitalist spirit has undergone a transformation.[42] In its heyday, Sombart explained, capitalism brought the merchant spirit to its "greatest bloom". The constant search for the best sales opportunities, the quick adaptation to daily changes in the markets, the titillating competition for customers - all these were essential traits of Hochkapitalismus. The system of economic organization in advanced capitalism was a “fluid” one. By contrast, late capitalism is a "bureaucratized capitalism", in which the spirit of commerce has vanished. The demise of the commercial spirit is not the cause of the bureaucratization of capitalism, but rather its expression; it could only eventuate when conditions had become so stable, that buying and selling occurred without much real marketing effort. At that stage, a "rigid system" already existed, and this was “typical” of late capitalism.[43]

In Modern Capitalism, Sombart did not present anything like a full-fledged, systematic synthesis of the emerging new capitalist order. That work still remained to be done. Concluding his 1928 Zürich lecture on the transformations of capitalism, Sombart stated:

"Today we are in a new era. It is obvious that [the beginning of] the new epoch is defined by the [first] World War. What this period is called is to an extent arbitrary, although of course some names will be more appropriate than others in particular situations. I have suggested the term 'late capitalism', because I know of no other expression which characterizes this era better. I hope that this term will be favourably received; I am aware, of course, of how much aversion there is, particularly among [academic] colleagues, to accepting unfamiliar new terminology – as Max Weber once put it: 'as if it were a question of using someone else's toothbrush.' There is always a possibility that other expressions will prevail. But what is most important is not the name, but the phenomenon itself, the thesis that this is a new era of economic life, as well as the issue of the characteristics of this era. If agreement can be reached about that, I would consider my task fullfilled".[44]

Other than a few articles and lectures, however, Sombart did not publish any comprehensive treatise on late capitalism. His thinking about the topic was disrupted in 1933 by the new Nazi government, when he was 70 years old (he died in 1941, when he was 78). Like many other leading German intellectuals, he wanted to survive as a scholar, and he hoped that Hitler's leadership would revive Germany from almost two decades of war, economic woes, social decay and human misery. There exists no evidence that he ever became a card-carrying member of the Nazi party, but he did begin to espouse a new sociological theory of "German socialism" (in opposition to e.g. Jewish socialism and Marxism), and in his new typology of socialisms, Nazism was one (preferred) socialism among others.[45] Whatever his real motives were, Sombart rhetorically aligned himself with the Nazi movement, while saving the integrity of his own scholarly perspective, and retaining intellectual independence, as a respected emeritus.

Because of his apparent Nazi sympathies in his last years[46] and his sociological portrayals of Jews and Judaism in some of his writings,[47] Sombart was often stereotyped as a "Nazi intellectual" and as antisemitic.[48] It meant that after World War II, his writings and ideas largely vanished from university curriculae.[49] Only in the 1980s[50] and 1990s[51] did significant scholarly interest in Sombart's intellectual legacy begin to revive, with new appraisals and studies of particular aspects of his large oeuvre.

Interwar years and World War II

edit

In the post–World War I reconstruction era, many of the wartime regulations in Europe continued, and the state played the leading role in repairing, rebuilding and reorganizing society.[52] According to historian Edward H. Carr, "In Europe after 1919, the planned economy... became the practice, if not the theory, of almost every state."[53] This had a strong influence on how the post-war order was interpreted by social scientists. Addressing the Kiel congress of the German Social-Democratic Party in 1927, Rudolf Hilferding claimed that:

 
Rudolf Hilferding and his wife, walking to the Reichstag in Berlin in June 1928

"In reality, organized capitalism means that the capitalist principle of laissez-faire is replaced by the socialist principle of planned production. This planned, deliberately managed form of economy is much more susceptible to the conscious influence of society, which means to the influence of the... compulsory organization of the whole of society, the state."[54]

The term "late capitalism" began to be used by socialists in continental Europe in the 1930s and 1940s, in the context of the Great Depression.[55] At that time, it was not an especially radical turn of phrase, because many people of different political persuasions really believed that the existing social order was doomed, or was at least ripe for renewal and transformation.[56] The European economy became highly regulated, and that reached a peak during the years of war economy in 1939–45.

During World War II, even leading American economists believed that the economic problems might eventually become insurmountable. In their book Capitalism since World War II, Philip Armstrong, Andrew Glyn and John Harrison commented that:

"Paul A. Samuelson, who later wrote the bestselling economics textbook published in the postwar years, raised in 1943 the probability of a 'nightmarish combination of the worst features of inflation and deflation', fearing that 'there would be ushered in the greatest period of unemployment and industrial dislocation which any economy has ever faced' (Samuelson, 1943, p. 51). He was speaking, it should be remembered, about the United States, which was relatively unscathed by hostilities. […] Joseph Schumpeter, an eminent economist, summed up the mood of alarm of the early forties: 'The all but general opinion seems to be that capitalist methods will be unequal to the task of reconstruction.' He regarded it as 'not open to doubt that the decay of capitalist society is very far advanced' (Schumpeter, 1943, p, 120)."[57]

 
Joseph Schumpeter at Harvard University, 1945

In his book Capitalism, socialism and democracy (1943), Schumpeter also stated:

"Can capitalism survive? No. I do not think it can. But this opinion of mine, like that of every other economist who has pronounced upon the subject, is in itself completely uninteresting. What counts in any attempt at social prognosis is not the Yes or No that sums up the facts and arguments which lead up to it but those facts and arguments themselves. (…) The thesis I shall endeavor to establish is that... [the very success of capitalism] undermines the social institutions which protect it, and “inevitably” creates conditions in which it will not be able to live and which strongly point to socialism as the heir apparent."[58]

Post–World War II era

edit

In Russia, the Marxist-Leninist doctrine of the (deepening) "general crisis of capitalism" in the imperialist epoch, and the theory of state monopoly capitalism, defined the official government perspective for the postwar era.[59] The historian Paolo Spriano describes how this caused the dismissal of one of Russia's top economists, after he dared to suggest that there would not be a deep capitalist crisis after the end of World War II:

 
1979 Soviet postal cover featuring a portrait of Eugen Varga

"Eugen Varga… argued that capitalism would be able to ward off, or at least to postpone, a general crisis. By May 1947 he was being subject to harsh criticism for this. He was soon relieved of many of his duties, and the Institute of World Economy and Politics, of which he had been the director, was closed down. The official line was that the capitalist system was poised on the brink of a catastrophic crisis. Indeed, the virulence and imperialist aggressivity of capitalism were said to result precisely from desperate attempts to avert this crisis by provoking tension, conflict, and war. Propagandistic use of this thesis became common in subsequent years".[60]

In the West, there had been similar expectations (across the whole political spectrum) that a severe systemic crisis would very likely occur after the war. When that did not happen, it was a surprise and a relief. However, what exactly could explain this turn of events is open to debate.[61] Different theories about the success of the postwar reconstruction effort have been proposed.[62]

One of the big geopolitical changes during and after World War 2 was the decolonization of many former colonies, often spearheaded by national liberation movements. To many observers, this trend signalled the end of the "classical" era of capitalist imperialism, and the start of a new global epoch, or at least a qualitative change in the global balance of power and the global states system. The socialist bloc of countries led by the Soviet Union and the People's Republic of China seemed to be gaining ground, suggesting that on a world scale, capitalism really was in decline.

The capitalism emerging from post-war reconstruction appeared to many analysts as a new type of capitalism, even although some of its traditional characteristics remained the same. This raised the question, "if capitalism had changed, how much did it change, and what was different or new about it? What are the political implications?". Particularly after the death of Joseph Stalin and the "thaw" of the official communist movement, this issue became a hot topic of debate at many leftwing conferences and in many books.[63] The controversy continued in numerous journals, including Monthly Review and New Left Review. According to professors Michael Charles Howard and John Edward King,

“At the end of the Second World war many Marxian and some non-Marxian) economists [had] anticipated that a severe economic downturn, possibly in the same league as the Great Depression, would follow hard on the heels of the peace. When, a dozen years later, the expected crisis had still not materialized and the accumulation of capital was still proceeding rapidly and smoothly in the advanced capitalist countries, the Marxists were under pressure to reappraise their entire political economy.”[64]

The concept of "late capitalism" was used in the 1960s, 1970s and 1980s in Europe by Western Marxists, socialists and other leftwing thinkers. Some examples can be mentioned to illustrate their concerns:

  • In 1965, Fritz Vilmar published Rüstung und Abrüstung im Spätkapitalismus ["Armament and Disarmament in Late Capitalism"].[65]
  • Leo Michielsen and Andre Gorz popularized the term "neo-capitalism" in France and Belgium, with new analyses of postwar capitalism.[66]
  • In 1968, Rudi Dutschke, a leading spokesman of the German student revolt, published a pamphlet entitled "The contradictions of late capitalism, the anti-authoritarian students and their relationship to the third world."[67]
  • Theodor Adorno preferred "late capitalism" over "industrial society," which was the theme of the 16th Congress of German Sociologists in 1968.[68]
  • In 1971, Leo Kofler published a book called Technologische Rationalität im Spätkapitalismus ("Technological Rationality in Late Capitalism").[69]
  • Claus Offe published his essay "Spätkapitalismus – Versuch einer Begriffsbestimmung" ("Late Capitalism—an Attempt at a Conceptual Definition") in 1972.[70]
  • In 1972, Alfred Sohn-Rethel published Die ökonomische Doppelnatur des Spätkapitalismus.[71]
  • In 1973, Jürgen Habermas published his Legitimationsprobleme im Spätkapitalismus (Legitimacy problems in late capitalism).[72]
  • In 1975, Ernest Mandel published his 1972 PhD thesis Late Capitalism in English at New Left Books.
  • In 1979, Volker Ronge published Bankpolitik im Spätkapitalismus: politische Selbstverwaltung des Kapitals?, a study of banking in late capitalism.[73]
  • In 1980, Herbert Marcuse also accepted the term in his reflections about the future of capitalism and socialism.[74]
  • In 1981, Winfried Wolf and Michel Capron extended Mandel's analysis of the long recession in Spätkapitalismus in den achtziger Jahren.[75]
  • Jacques Derrida preferred neo-capitalism to post- or late-capitalism.[76]

From the mid-1970s to the 1980s, the use of the concept of late capitalism spread to English-speaking countries.

Ernest Mandel's perspective

edit

When Ernest Mandel adopted the term “late capitalism”, he had in mind the perspectives of Lenin, Trotsky and the Communist International about the 20th century.[77] The theoretical framework was, that the world-historical epoch of capitalist decline began with World War 1 (or even earlier, with the uprising in St Petersburg in 1905). Mandel regarded "late capitalism" as a new historical stage within the epoch of capitalist imperialism; contrary to expectations in the interwar years, the labour movement suffered heavy defeats, and world capitalism had gained a new 'lease of life'.[78] Mandel did not abandon Lenin’s analysis of imperialism, but modified it, in the light of the experience of the post-World War 2 reconstruction era, decolonization and the global political impact of Stalinism. So the term "late" in "late capitalism" referred to the unexpected and belated revival and "third age" of capitalism after World War II, seemingly contradicting the theory of capitalist decline.

 
Ernest Mandel, talking with academics at the “Capitalism in the 1970s” conference (Tilburg Polytech, The Netherlands), 10 September 1970

Mandel aimed specifically to explain the long economic boom during 1947–73,[79] which showed the fastest economic growth ever seen in human history.[80] His analyses[81] stimulated new interest in the theory of long waves in economic development.[82] The chapters for his book Late capitalism were put together quite rapidly, using earlier draft texts and reading notes as well as lecture notes written when Mandel was visiting lecturer in Berlin in 1970/71.[83] Obtaining a Phd degree was crucial for Mandel (in his late 40s) to get a permanent academic position.[84]

According to Ernest Mandel, late capitalism involves the commodification and industrialisation of more and more parts of the economy and society, where human services are turned into commercial products.[85] Mandel believed that "[f]ar from representing a 'post-industrial society', late capitalism [...] constitutes generalized universal industrialization for the first time in history".[86] At the same time, the role of the state in the economy and society kept growing. During and after World War II, the size of enterprises, ownership concentration and the scale of mass production increased, the activities of multinational corporations expanded,[87] and there were more and more attempts at coordinated economic planning (or "economic programming").[88]

Until the late 1960s, Mandel preferred to use the term "neo-capitalism", which was most often used by leftwing intellectuals in Belgium and France at that time.[89] This idea drew attention to the fact that new characteristics of capitalism had emerged in its postwar recovery. At the time, however, ultraleftist Marxists objected to the term "neo-capitalism", because, according to them, it might suggest that capitalism was no longer capitalism, and this would lead to reformist deviations rather than to the total overthrow of capitalism.[90] The proof of this seemed to be that Mandel argued—at the zenith of the capitalist postwar boom—for "anti-capitalist structural reforms".[91]

Mandel distinguished three main historical stages in the development of the capitalist mode of production:

  • Freely competitive capitalist production, roughly from 1700 to 1870, through the growth of industrial capital in national (domestic) markets, especially in Western Europe and North America.
  • The phase of monopoly capitalism, roughly from 1870 to 1940 was characterized by the imperialist competition for international markets, export of capital and the exploitation of colonial territories. The world was carved up into spheres of influence, in which each great power had its own empire containing colonies, semi-colonies and dependent territories.
  • The epoch of late capitalism emerging out of the Second World War, which has as its dominant features the multinational corporation, globalization, consumerism, decolonization and increasingly internationalized financial markets.[92] Characteristic of this epoch are corporate self-financing, a great expansion of foreign direct investment, and the formation of global systems regulating credit, currencies, commodities and capital assets.

The French edition of Mandel's Late Capitalism was titled The third age of capitalism.[93]

In part, Mandel's analysis was a critique of Henryk Grossmann's breakdown theory, according to which capitalism would collapse after a series of business cycles, because of insufficient surplus value production.[94] But Mandel also criticized the methodological approach of Rudolf Hilferding, Rosa Luxemburg, Nikolai Bukharin, Otto Bauer, Michal Kalecki, and Charles Bettelheim.[95] One of Mandel's aims was also to revive and re-evaluate the classical controversies in Marxian economics - savagely repressed in the Stalin era - in a new historical setting. He argued that important qualitative changes occurred in the functioning of the capitalist system during and after World War II. Intermediate between the periodization of business cycles across two centuries and the postulated ultimate collapse of capitalism, Mandel argued, there were epochs of faster and slower economic growth.

In the history of the capitalist mode of production since the 1820s, "long waves" of economic growth could be observed in time series data on economic activity. These waves typically lasted about 20 to 25 years, from peak to trough or from trough to the next peak.[96] During the ascending phase, cyclical upturns were typically stronger and downturns were weaker, while during the receding phase, the downturns were typically deeper and the upturns were weaker. However, Mandel did not accept the hypothesis of Nikolai Kondratiev that there existed endogenously predetermined "long cycles" in the history of capitalism.[97] Every capitalist boom ends with a fall of the average rate profit, but there existed no enduring economic mechanism which "automatically" created an economic recovery after a severe economic depression; much depended on state policy decisions, and on the outcome of political battles between warring social classes and class fractions (the rise and fall of mass unemployment was not simply an automatic "mechanism" of the capitalist "engine", but influenced by political factors, labour disputes and specific business conditions).

The political significance of the economic long waves was that they shape the life-experiences of different generations, the lessons drawn from those experiences, and the patterns of workers' struggles - nationally and globally. Political thinking from the previous era, phase or conjuncture had to be readjusted to the current and future situations. When demand for labour was high, workers were generally in a strong position, but in times of mass unemployment, workers were generally in a weaker position. Ernest Mandel sometimes referred to a "class struggle cycle" alongside the ups and downs of economic activity.[98] In a series of publications, Mandel analyzed the dynamics and results of the unexpected postwar boom, the long world recession of 1974 to 1982,[99] the debt crisis of developing countries, the 1987 stock crash and the long-term systemic crisis of late capitalism, as basis for his projections about the long-term prospects of world capitalism in the future.[100]

In the tradition of the orthodox Marxists,[101] Mandel tried to characterize the nature of the modern epoch as a whole, with reference to the main long-run laws of motion of capitalism specified by Marx.[102] These laws of motion were: 1. The capitalist compulsion to accumulate and invest for profit, under the pressure of business competition. 2. The tendency towards constant technological revolutions, which increase productivity. 3. The constant attempt to increase absolute and relative surplus value. 4. The tendency toward increasing concentration and centralization of capital. 5. The tendency for the organic composition of capital to increase. 6. The tendency of the average profit rate on capital invested in industries to decrease, in the long term. 7. The inevitability of class struggle (or class conflicts) under capitalism. 8. The tendency of the working class to grow in size and social polarization to increase. 9. The tendency towards growing objective socialization of labour. 10. The inevitability of recurrent economic crises in capitalist society.[103]

Mandel thought that six basic variables were most important for the long-term global growth pattern of the capitalist mode of production and its average profitability: (i) the evolution of the general and sectoral organic compositions of capital; (ii) the division of circulating and fixed capital in constant capital; (iii) the evolution of the rate of surplus value; (iv) the development of the rate of accumulation, and more specifically the reinvestment of surplus value in production; (v) the development of the turnover of capital (speed, volume and type); and (vi) the interactions between the producer goods sector ("Department I") and the consumer goods sector ("Department II"). These variables could to an extent fluctuate semi-independently of each other.[104]

Fredric Jameson's interpretation

edit

In his book Postmodernism, or, the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism.[105] Fredric Jameson was partly inspired by Mandel's theory of late capitalism. Jameson's theory of postmodernity portrays a new mode of cultural production (developments in literature, film, fine art, video, social theory, etc.) which differs markedly from the preceding era of Modernism.

 
Fredric Jameson, giving a lecture at Porto Alegre in Brazil, 4 January 2004

In the modernist era (circa 1900-1960s), the dominant ideology was that society could be re-engineered on the basis of objective scientific and technical knowledge, and on the basis of a broad consensus about the meaning of progress. In the second half of the 20th century, however, modernism was gradually eclipsed by postmodernist culture. Postmodernist attitudes are skeptical about social engineering and lack consensus about the meaning of human progress. In the course of rapid technological and social change, all the old certainties and traditional forms of association began to break down. This also began to destabilize every part of life, making almost everything (from relationships, foods and job positions to accommodation, fashion, household appliances and political leaderships) malleable, changeable, transient and impermanent.[106]

Jameson argues that "every position on postmodernism today — whether apologia or stigmatization — is also...necessarily an implicitly or explicitly political stance on the nature of multinational capitalism today".[107] A section of Jameson's analysis has been reproduced on the Marxists Internet Archive. Jameson regards the late capitalist stage as a new and previously unparalleled development with a global reach—whether defined as a multinational or informational capitalism. At the same time, late capitalism diverges from Marx's prognosis for the final stage of capitalism.[108]

Corey Robin's argument

edit

In a paywalled blog article published in June 2025 by New Left Review on its website,[109] the New York politicial scientist Corey Robin directly comments on this Wikipedia article on late capitalism (although he does not acknowledge his source, and does not quote from it directly).[110] Robin is currently working on a political theory of capitalism titled King Capital,[111] and he tries to develop the wiki content into a narrative with greater eloquence, erudition and depth, from his own perspective. In 2025-26, he will be a Fellow at the Institute for Advanced Study at Princeton.[112]

He argues that late capitalism is “an ambiguous term”, because it could imply “the demise of something” but also “its refinement and advance”. However, he claims that “late capitalism is not an idea that lends itself to revolution or a vision of progress. It may express a wish to be rid of capitalism. But mostly it works as a theory of turning points that never turn – or worse.”[113] In Robin’s view, almost all of the theorists of late capitalism got it wrong (except perhaps that some hedged their bets sufficiently to save their own argument). Robin concludes:

”More than a dictate of economics, profit is a question of power. Unlike a machine, the power of workers, concerted, cannot be determined in advance. How much power the workers can exercise – and how much profit the capitalist can extract – is an open question, answered only in the struggle itself. In the early days of late capitalism, capital learned that lesson. Whether we are in the last or merely the latest days of capitalism will be determined by whether and how labour learns it, too.”[114]

Analogous to Marcel van der Linden,[115] Corey Robin feels that workers still have things to learn, to be able to assume their role in changing the course of history.[116] They don’t know whether they have won the war, or whether they can win it, before they have fought the battle. In the Communist Manifesto, Marx and Engels commented in this sense that “The [written] history of all hitherto existing society is the history of class struggles… an uninterrupted, now hidden, now open fight, a fight that each time ended, either in a revolutionary re-constitution of society at large, or in the common ruin of the contending classes.”[117] However, Robin has nothing to say about the parasitism of late capitalism,[118] and the role of the academic class in exploiting, discriminating and parasitizing the workers. Robin’s approach to social power contrasts with Marx’s interpretation of historical processes and with Mandel’s parametric determinism (or "the dialectic of objective and subjective factors"[119]). According to Marx, people do make their own history with their actions, but not in a void, not simply under self-selected social and material circumstances, but under given conditions inherited from the past.[120] Marx reached the insight that "the educators have to be educated themselves", i.e. they have to become learners in order to understand properly what they are talking about.[121]

Other analyses of the epoch

edit

Immanuel Wallerstein believed that capitalism was in the process of being replaced by another world system.[122] The American literary critic and cultural theorist Frederic Jameson thought Rudolf Hilferding's term the latest stage of capitalism (jüngster Kapitalismus) perhaps more prudent and less prophetic-sounding[123] but Jameson often used "late capitalism" in his writings. Hegel's theme of "the end of history" was rekindled by Kojève in his Introduction to the Reading of Hegel.

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ For example, John E. Elliott, "Karl Marx's Theory of Socio-Institutional Transformation in Late-Stage Capitalism".In: Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. 18, No. 2, June 1984, pp. 383-391; Oluwatoni Olujinmi, "Late-stage capitalism: what is it and what are its main features". World Excellence, The #1 Magazine for CEO's, 28 May 2023.[1]
  2. ^ Günther Chaloupek, “Spätkapitalismus“. Stagnationstheorien deutscher Ökonomen zwischen den Weltkriegen”, in: Volker Caspari (ed.), Stagnations- und Deflationstheorien. Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomischen Theorie XXXVIII. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, 2021, pp. 113- 140, at p. 116; Werner Sombart, "Prinzipielle Eigenart des modernen Kapitalismus". In: C. Brinkmann et al., Grundriss der Sozialwissenschaft, Band IV.1. ("Spezifische Elemente der modernen kapitalistische Wirtschaft", 1 Teil) Tübingen: Verlag J.C.B. Mohr, 1925, pp 1-26, at p. 26. Reprinted in: Alexander Ebner & Helge Peukert (eds.), Werner Sombart, Nationalökonomie als Kapitalismustheorie. Ausgewählte Schriften. Weimar bei Marburg: Metropolis Verlag, 2002, pp. 377-421.
  3. ^ Günther Chaloupek, ""Werner Sombart's 'Spätkapitalismus' und die langfristige Wirtschaftsentwicklung'". Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Vol. 22, Issue 3, 1996, pp. 385-400, at p. 386.
  4. ^ Werner Sombart, “Economic theory and economic history” [1929], in: Journal of Institutional Economics, Vol. 2, Issue 1, April 2006, pp. 109-125; Eric J. Hobsbawm (ed.), Karl Marx: Pre-capitalist economic formations. New York: International Publishers, 2007.
  5. ^ Friedrich Engels, “Supplement to Capital Vol. 3”, in: Karl Marx, Capital Vol. 3, Penguin edition 1981, p. 1031.[2] Werner Sombart, "Zur Kritik des ökonomischen Systems von Karl Marx". In: Heinrich Braun (ed.), Archiv für soziale Gesetzgebung und Statistik, Vol. 7, No. 4, 1894, pp. 555-594 (Berlin: Carl Heymann’s Verlag).[3] (English translation: Werner Sombart , "A contribution to the critique of Karl Marx's economic system" (1894), in: Richard B. Day & Daniel F. Gaido (ed.), Responses to Marx's Capital: from Rudolf Hilferding to Isaak Illich Rubin. Leiden/Boston: Brill Publishers, 2018, pp. 162-210. Friedrich Engels, “Letter to Werner Sombart”, London, March 11, 1895. Marx/Engels Selected Correspondence, Moscow: Progress Publishers edition, 1975, pp. 454-456.[4].
  6. ^ Friedrich Lenger, Werner Sombart 1863-1941: eine Biographie, 3rd edition. Munchen: Verlag C.H. Beck, 2012, chapter 4.
  7. ^ Friedrich Pollock, Sombarts "Widerlegung" des Marxismus. Leipzig: Hirschfeld, 1926 (a pamphlet).
  8. ^ Francis X. Sutton, "The social and economic philosophy of Werner Sombart: the sociology of capitalism", in: Harry Elmer Barnes (ed.), An introduction to the history of sociology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press 1948, pp. 316-331.
  9. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late capitalism. London: New Left Books, 1975; Robert Rowthorn, "Late capitalism" [review essay]. New Left Review, July-August 1976. Reprinted in: Robert Rowthorn, Capitalism, conflict and inflation: essays in political economy. London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1980, pp. 95-128.
  10. ^ During World War II, there were no battlefields in the North American continent itself (there was only the Attack on Pearl Harbor and a few other incursions). This advantaged American and Canadian economic development vis-a-vis Europe and other regions in the world, the latter which suffered heavy economic and infrastructural war damage. Some historians prefer to date the emergence of a new capitalist era in North America already before World War II began, during the days of the New Deal or else from the start of a war economy in 1941 (see War Powers Act of 1941).
  11. ^ For example, Jonathan Crary, Late capitalism and the ends of sleep. London: Verso, 2013; Benjamin Y. Fong, Death and mastery : psychoanalytic drive theory and the subject of late capitalism. Columbia University Press, New York, 2016; Anna Kornbluh, Immediacy : or, the style of too-late capitalism. London: Verso, 2023.
  12. ^ David Inglis, "Better late than modern? Between ‘late capitalism’ and ‘late modernity’". European Journal of Social Theory, Volume 27, Issue 4, 2024, pp. 521–539, at p. 522. Cf. Alessandro Gerosa, The Hipster Economy: Taste and Authenticity in Late Modern Capitalism. London: UCL Press, 2024.
  13. ^ Annie Lowrey, "Why the Phrase 'Late Capitalism' Is Suddenly Everywhere". In: The Atlantic, 1 May 2017.[5] See also: Kimberley Amadeo, "What is Late Stage Capitalism?". The Balance (New York), 17 June 2024.[6]; David Aviles, "We live in a time of ‘late capitalism’. But what does that mean? And what’s so late about it?" The Conversation, December 7, 2022 [7]; David Elias Aviles Espinoza, "Unpacking late capitalism". University of Sydney News, 20 December 2022.[8]
  14. ^ Dominic Green, "‘Naples 1925’ Review: The Birth of Critical Theory". Wall Street Journal, 8 November 2024.[9] Living in the End Times is a book by Slavoj Žižek, published by Verso Books in 2010.
  15. ^ Chine McDonald, “Doom sells: why everyone’s talking about the end times.” MSN News, 15 August 2025.[10] (also published in the Financial Times, 15 August 2025).
  16. ^ Harry Targ, Challenging late Capitalism, Neoliberal Globalization, & Militarism. Carl Davidson, 2006, p. 15–26.
  17. ^ Hans Neisser, "Stability in late capitalism". In: Social Research, Vol. 21, No. 1, Spring 1954, pp. 85-106, p. 106
  18. ^ Krugman, Paul (22 December 2018). "Opinion – The Case for a Mixed Economy". The New York Times. Retrieved 20 January 2019.
  19. ^ Michael Bleaney, The rise and fall of Keynesian economics. Houndmills: Macmillan Education Ltd, 1985, chapter 2, pp. 41-42.
  20. ^ "Modest Declines in Positive Views of ‘Socialism’ and ‘Capitalism’ in U.S.". Pew Research Center, 19 September 2022.[11]
  21. ^ Ankie Hoogvelt, Globalization and the postcolonial world, 2nd edition. Houndmills: Palgrave, 1997, p. xiii (emphasis added).
  22. ^ Human Development Report 2019. New York: United Nations Development Programme, 2019.
  23. ^ F.R. Hansen, The breakdown of capitalism. A history of the idea in Western Marxism, 1883–1983. London: Routledge, 1985.
  24. ^ Efforts to create a coherent picture of the epoch were especially evident in the congresses of the Comintern, but also became standard fare in the resolutions of national Communist parties.
  25. ^ Lenin, Vladimir Ilyich (July 19, 1920), Report On The International Situation And The Fundamental Tasks Of The Communist International, retrieved November 29, 2019
  26. ^ John Riddell (ed.), Lenin’s Struggle for a Revolutionary International. Documents, 1907-1916: The Preparatory Years. New York: Pathfinder Press, 1984; "The Platform of the Communist International", in: Theses, Resolutions and Manifestos of the First Four Congresses of the Third International, translated by Alix Holt and Barbara Holland. London: Ink Links 1980.[12]
  27. ^ Eugen Varga, The Decline of Capitalism. London: The Communist Party of Great Britain for the Communist International, 1924[13]; Eugen Varga, The Decline of Capitalism: The Economics of a Period of the Decline of Capitalism after Stabilisation. London: The Communist Party of Great Britain for the Communist International, 1928. These texts are reprinted in André Mommen (ed.) Eugen Varga: Selected Political and Economic Writings. From the Hungarian Revolution to Orthodox Economic Theory in The USSR. Leiden: Brill, 2020.
  28. ^ Lenin, Vladimir Ilyich (June 1916), Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism, retrieved November 29, 2019; Jane Degras (ed.), The Communist International, 1919-1943. London: Routledge, 1971.
  29. ^ V.I. Lenin, Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism (1916), chapter X.[14]
  30. ^ Gerd Hardach et al., A short history of socialist economic thought. New York: St Martins Press, 1978, chapter 4, p. 63f.
  31. ^ David Inglis, "Better late than modern? Between ‘late capitalism’ and ‘late modernity’". European Journal of Social Theory, Volume 27, Issue 4, 2024, pp. 521–539.
  32. ^ This is pointed out by Günther Chaloupek, “Spätkapitalismus“. Stagnationstheorien deutscher Ökonomen zwischen den Weltkriegen”, in: Volker Caspari (ed.), Stagnations- und Deflationstheorien. Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomischen Theorie XXXVIII. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, 2021, pp. 113- 140, at p. 116. The article is: Werner Sombart, "Prinzipielle Eigenart des modernen Kapitalismus". In: C. Brinkmann et al., Grundriss der Sozialwissenschaft, Band IV.1. (Spezifische Elemente der modernen kapitalistische Wirtschaft, 1e Teil) Tübingen: Verlag J.C.B. Mohr, 1925, pp 1-26, at p. 26. Reprinted in: Alexander Ebner & Helge Peukert (eds.), Werner Sombart, Nationalökonomie als Kapitalismustheorie. Ausgewählte Schriften. Weimar bei Marburg: Metropolis Verlag, 2002.
  33. ^ Specifically, Werner Sombart, "Die Wandlungen des Kapitalismus" [="The transformations of capitalism", a lecture given at the conference of the Vereins für Sozialpolitik in Zürich, on 13 September 1928]. In: Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 28, 1928, pp. 243-256. Transcripts of the conference were published in 1929: Franz Boese (ed.), Wandlungen des Kapitalismus. Auslandanleihen. Kredit und Konjunktur auf Grund der stenographischen Niederschrift. München, Duncker & Humblot 1929. See also Talcott Parsons, "'Capitalism' In Recent German Literature: Sombart and Weber." Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 36, No. 6, December 1928, pp. 641-661.
  34. ^ Werner Sombart, Modern Capitalism — Volume 1: The Pre-Capitalist Economy: A systematic historical depiction of Pan-European economic life from its origins to the present day, parts I and II. Wellington, New Zealand: K. A. Nitz Publishing, 2019 and 2023.
  35. ^ Frederick Louis Nussbaum, A History of the Economic Institutions of Modern Europe. An Introduction of Der Moderne Kapitalismus of Werner Sombart. New York: F.S. Crofts & Co., 1933 (Literary Licensing Inc. reprint 2012).
  36. ^ “The history of the editions of Der moderne Kapitalismus is confusing because while there are a total of some six editions, there are only three different ones: the first one from 1902, the second one from 1916/1917, and the final edition from 1928. The third edition from 1919, the fourth edition from 1921, the fifth edition from 1922, and the sixth edition from 1924 are all unchanged reprints from the edition from 1916/1917. Add to that the fact that the 1916 version was the first volume and the 1917 version was the second volume complicates things more. And, the full second edition had appeared in three volumes: the first book was a single volume while the second book was split into two. Then, the 1921 volume was composed of four volumes with the first and the second book split into two. In 1927 Sombart published an additional book in two volumes and the following year the final edition of Der moderne Kapitalismus appeared in six volumes but in different versions: some have the first four volumes in one binding and the second version in a different type while others have all six volumes look the same.” – Christoper Adair-Toteff, Werner Sombart and the ‘Spirit’ of modern capitalism: rediscovering a classic. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan/Springer, 2024, pp. 97-98.
  37. ^ In the third volume of Sombart’s Modern Capitalism, the word "Spätkapitalismus" is mentioned six times.
  38. ^ Werner Sombart, "Prinzipielle Eigenart des modernen Kapitalismus". In: C. Brinkmann et al., Grundriss der Sozialwissenschaft, Band IV.1. (Spezifische Elemente der modernen kapitalistische Wirtschaft, 1e Teil) Tübingen: Verlag J.C.B. Mohr, 1925, pp 1-26; Werner Sombart, "Die Wandlungen des Kapitalismus".In: Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 28, 1928, pp. 243-256; Werner Sombart, "Economic Theory and Economic History". The Economic History Review, Vol. 2, No. 1, January 1929, pp. 1-19; Werner Sombart, "Kapitalismus". In: Alfred Vierkandt (ed.), Handwörterbuch der Soziologie [1931], 2nd edition. Stuttgart: Enke Verlag, 1931 , pp. 258-277; Werner Sombart, Die Zukunft des Kapitalismus[=The future of capitalism, a lecture dated 29 February 1932, edited by Elmar Altvater]. Berlin: Mimesis Verlag, 2017; Werner Sombart, "Capitalism", in: Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences, Volume 3. New York: Macmillan, 1930, pp. 195-208. See further: Christoper Adair-Toteff, Werner Sombart and the ‘Spirit’ of modern capitalism: rediscovering a classic. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan/Springer, 2024, chapter 5.
  39. ^ Werner Sombart, Der Moderne Kapitalismus (3 Vols.). Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, 1986 reprint, Vol. 3, p. XI.
  40. ^ Werner Sombart, Das Wirtschaftsleben in Zeitalter des Hochkapitalismus [Vol. 3, Part 2]. München/Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot, 1927.
  41. ^ Ibid., p. XII.
  42. ^ Ibid.
  43. ^ Ibid., pp. 805-806.
  44. ^ Werner Sombart, "Die Wandlungen des Kapitalismus" [Vortrag, gehalten auf der Tagung des Vereins für Sozialpolitik zu Zürich am 13e September 1928]. In: Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 28, pp. 243-256, at pp. 255-256. At almost exactly the same time, Joseph A. Schumpeter wrote: "Capitalism is... in so obvious a process of transformation into something else, that it is not the fact, but only the interpretation of the fact, about which it is possible to disagree.(…) Capitalism, whilst economically stable, and even gaining in stability, creates, by rationalising the human mind, a mentality and a style of life incompatible with its own fundamental conditions, motives and social institutions and will be changed, although not by economic necessity and probably even at some sacrifice of economic welfare, into an order of things which it will be merely a matter of taste to call Socialism or not." Joseph Schumpeter, "The instability of capitalism". The Economic Journal, Vol. 38, Issue 151, September 1928, pp. 361—386.
  45. ^ Werner Sombart, A new social philosophy. Princeton University Press/Oxford University Press, 1937, p. 113. For a rightwing perspective, see: Herman Lebovics, “Werner Sombart: the age of late capitalism”. In: Lebovics, Social Conservatism and the Middle Class in Germany, 1914-1933. Princeton Universty Press, 1969, pp. 49-78.
  46. ^ For more information, see: Jenica M. Kramer, "Werner Sombart and National Socialism". Portland, Oregon: Working Paper No. 19, Economics Department of Portland State University, 15 March 2019.[15]
  47. ^ See for example: Werner Sombart, The Jews and modern capitalism. Kitchener: Batoche Books, 2001.
  48. ^ However, his last book Vom Menschen: Versuch einer geisteswissenschaftlichen Anthropologie. [Humans: an attempt at a spiritual-scientific anthropology] (1938) was certainly not to the taste of Nazi officials, and it was difficult to get it published. According to the antisemitic ideologue Theodor Fritsch, Sombart was far too friendly to Jewry in his analysis about the Jews and capitalism, but Fritsch (like many other antisemitists) was not averse to plagiarizing Sombart's ideas to bolster his own case. See: Jerry Z. Muller, The Mind and the Market: Capitalism in Modern European Thought. New York: Alfred A. Knopf 2002, p. 255; Theodor Fritsch [under the pseudonym of F. Roderich-Stoltheim], The riddle of the Jews' success. Leipzig: Hammer Verlag, 1927, chapter 6.[16] According to Christoper Adair-Toteff, “…a careful reading of Die Juden reveals that not only was Sombart not anti-Semitic but that he was arguing that the Jewish religious philosophy was a major factor for the development of capitalism.” - Christoper Adair-Toteff, Werner Sombart and the ‘Spirit’ of modern capitalism: rediscovering a classic. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan/Springer, 2024, p. 163.
  49. ^ Reiner Grundmann and Nico Stehr, "Why Is Werner Sombart Not Part of the Core of Classical Sociology?: From Fame to (Near) Oblivion." Journal of Classical Sociology, Volume 1, Issue 2, 2001.
  50. ^ Bernhard vom Brocke (ed.), Sombart's "Moderner Kapitalismus": Materialien zur Kritik und Rezeption. München: Deutscher Taschenbuch Verlag, 1987.
  51. ^ Jürgen Backhaus (ed.), Werner Sombart (1863-1941), Social scientist. Vol. 1: His life and Work, Vol. 2: His Theoretical Approach Reconsidered, Vol. 3: Then and Now. Weimar bei Marburg: Metropolis Verlag, 1996; Jürgen Backhaus (ed.), Werner Sombart (1863 — 1941) — Klassiker der Sozialwissenschaften Eine kritische Bestandsaufnahme. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag, 2000; Nico Stehr & Reiner Grundmann (eds.), Werner Sombart: Economic Life in the Modern Age. New Brunswick: Transaction, 2001; Christopher Adair-Toteff, Werner Sombart und der „Geist“ des modernen Kapitalismus. Wiederentdeckung eines Klassikers. Cham: Springer Gabler, 2025. Translated at Christoper Adair-Toteff, Werner Sombart and the ‘Spirit’ of modern capitalism: rediscovering a classic. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan/Springer, 2024.
  52. ^ Ivan T. Berend, An economic history of twentieth-century Europe. Cambridge University Press, 2016, chapter 2.
  53. ^ Edward H. Carr, The Twenty Years' Crisis. New York: Harper & Row, 1964, p. 51 (cited in Ivan T. Berend, An economic history of twentieth-century Europe. Cambridge University Press, 2016, p.58.
  54. ^ Cited in Berend, op. cit., p. 57.
  55. ^ See, for example, Natalie Moszkowska's Zur Dynamik des Spätkapitalismus. Zurich: Verlag Der Aufbruch, 1943.
  56. ^ How Marxist economists viewed the Great Depression in the 1930s is discussed in M.C. Howard and J.E. King, A history of Marxian economics, Vol. 2, 1919-1990. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992, chapter 1, pp. 3-23.
  57. ^ Philip Armstrong, Andrew Glyn and John Harrison, Capitalism since World War II: the making and breakup of the great boom. London: Fontana paperbacks, 1984, p. 23. Republished in a new edition, with a rewrite of Part III, as: Philip Armstrong, Andrew Glyn and John Harrison, Capitalism since 1945. Oxford: Blackwell, 1991, pp. 4-5. The references are to Paul A. Samuelson, "Full employment after the war" and Joseph Schumpeter, "Capitalism in the post-war world", both included in Seymour E. Harris (ed.), Post-war economic problems. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1943, pp. 27-54, 113-126.
  58. ^ Joseph A. Schumpeter, Capitalism, socialism and democracy, 5th edition. London: Routledge, 1976, p. 61. This was an elaboration of the thesis presented in Joseph Schumpeter, "The instability of capitalism". The Economic Journal, Vol. 38, Issue 151, September 1928, pp. 361—386. It is quite likely that Schumpeter borrowed many of his ideas from Werner Sombart and other German or Austrian scholars.
  59. ^ Gerd Hardach et al., A short history of socialist economic thought. New York: St Martins Press, 1978, chapter 4.
  60. ^ Paolo Spriano, Stalin and the European Communists. London: Verso, 1985, p. 281; André Mommen, Stalin's Economist. The Economic Contributions of Jenö Varga. London: Routledge, 2011 (Eugen Varga was rehabilitated only after Stalin's death). Eugen Varga, "Die marxistische Krisentheorie und das Studium der Konjunktur". In: Wirtschaftswissenschaft (Berlin, Verlag Die Wissenschaft), Vol. 9, No. 6, June 1961.
  61. ^ Philip Armstrong, Andrew Glyn and John Harrison, Capitalism since World War II: the making and breakup of the great boom. London: Fontana paperbacks, 1984, Part 1: post-war reconstruction, 1945-1950.
  62. ^ For example, Charlie Giattino states that during the US post-war baby boom 1946-1964, the fertility rate averaged nearly 4 children per woman, twice as many as in the 1930s (according to US Census data). An estimated 70 million new people were born in the US between 1946 and 1964. In 1964, this baby boom generation represented almost 40% of the total US population (Charlie Giattino, "The 'baby boom' saw a sharp rise in the fertility rate in the United States". Our world in data, 10 October 2024). [17]  This article incorporates text from this source, which is available under the CC BY 4.0 license.
  63. ^ One of the early scholarly publications was Shigeto Tsuru (ed.), Has capitalism changed? An international symposium on the nature of contemporary capitalism. Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten Publishers, 1961. It featured contributions by John Strachey, Paul Sweezy, Charles Bettelheim, Yakov A. Kronrod, Maurice Dobb, Paul A. Baran, and John Kenneth Galbraith.
  64. ^ M.C. Howard and J.E. King, A history of Marxian economics, Vol. 2, 1919-1990. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992, chapter 4, pp. 75-90, at p. 75.
  65. ^ Fritz Vilmar, Rüstung und Abrüstung im Spätkapitalismus (1965, reprint Reinbek bei Hamburg: Rowohlt Verlag, 1973).
  66. ^ Leo Michielsen, Neo-kapitalisme. Brussel: Jacquemotte Stichting, 1969. André Gorz, Stratégie ouvriére et néocapitalisme, Paris: Le Seuil, 1964.
  67. ^ Rudi Dutschke, Die Widersprüche des Spätkapitalismus, die antiautoritären Studenten und ihr Verhältnis zur Dritten Welt, in: U. Bergmann, R. Dutschke, W. Lefevre, B. Rabehl, Rebellion der Studenten oder Die neue Opposition. Reinbek bei Hamburg : Rowohlt Verlag, 1968.[18]
  68. ^ Theodor W. Adorno (ed.) Spätkapitalismus oder Industriegesellschaft. Verhandlungen des 16. Deutschen Soziologentages. Stuttgart, 1969.
  69. ^ Leo Kofler, Technologische Rationalität im Spätkapitalismus. Frankfurt: Makol Verlag, 1971.
  70. ^ *Claus Offe, Strukturprobleme ds kapitalistischen Staates. Frankfurt: Suhrkamp, 1972, pp. 7–25.
  71. ^ Alfred Sohn-Rethel, Die ökonomische Doppelnatur des Spätkapitalismus. Luchterhand: Darmstad/Nieuwied, 1972.
  72. ^ Jürgen Habermas, Legitimationsprobleme im Spätkapitalismus Frankfurt: Suhrkamp, 1973.
  73. ^ Volker Ronge, Bankpolitik im Spätkapitalismus: politische Selbstverwaltung des Kapitals? Frankfurt am Main : Suhrkamp, 1979.
  74. ^ Herbert Marcuse, "Protosocialism and Late Capitalism: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis Based on Bahro's Analysis". International Journal of Politics, Vol. 10 No. 2/3, Summer-Fall 1980, 25–48.
  75. ^ Winfried Wolf and Michel Capron, Spätkapitalismus in den achtziger Jahren. Bilanz der Weltwirtschaftsrezession 1980/81; die Strukturkrise der Autoindustrie und der Stahlbranche. Frankfurt/Main : ISP, 1981.
  76. ^ Catherine Malabou and Jacques Derrida, Counterpath: traveling with Jacques Derrida. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2004, p. 114-115. [19]
  77. ^ The early Comintern analysis of the nature of the epoch is well documented in André Mommen (ed.), Eugen Varga: Selected Political and Economic Writings. From the Hungarian Revolution to Orthodox Economic Theory in The USSR. Leiden: Brill, 2020, Part 2.
  78. ^ Manuel Kellner, Against capitalism and bureaucracy: Ernest Mandel’s theoretical contributions. Chicago: Haymarket, 2023, pp. 53-71.
  79. ^ Ernest Mandel, "History and the laws of motion of capitalism" [Lecture at Tilburg Polytech, The Netherlands, 1970]. Amsterdam: International Institute for Research and Education, translated 13 June 2023.[20]
  80. ^ The Jameson Reader, p. 257.
  81. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late Capitalism. London: New Left Books, 1975, chapter 4: "'Long waves' in the history of capitalism"; Ernest Mandel, Long waves of capitalist development: a Marxist interpretation (2nd. edition). London: Verso, 1995.
  82. ^ Christopher Freeman (ed.), Long waves in the world economy. London: Frances Pinter Publishers, 1984; Alfred Kleinknecht, Ernest Mandel and Immanuel Wallerstein (eds.), New findings in long-wave research. Houndmills, UK: Macmillan Press, 1992; Francisco Louçã & Jan Reijnders (eds.), The foundations of long wave theory: models and methodology, Vols. 1 and 2. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 1999; Grace K. Hong, The Ruptures of American Capital (2006) p. 152.
  83. ^ Jan Willem Stutje, Ernest Mandel: a rebel's dream deferred. London: Verso, 2009, p. 138.
  84. ^ In 1969, the US State Department refused Mandel a visa to visit the USA for a debate with John Kenneth Galbraith, at Stanford University in California. In 1975, Mandel was branded a “Trotskyite terrorist” by a security committee of the US Senate, because he had said that he considered armed struggle a defensible strategy in Latin America. Only years later, under Jimmy Carter’s presidency, did brief visits to the US (with restrictions) become possible again. See: Jan Willem Stutje, Ernest Mandel: a rebel's dream deferred. London: Verso, 2009, pp. 185-186.
  85. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late Capitalism (London: New Left Books, 1975) p. 406.
  86. ^ Ibid., p. 387
  87. ^ Ernest Mandel, "International capitalism and 'supranationality'" [1967], reprinted in: Hugo Radice (ed.), International firms and modern imperialism. Harmondsworth: Penguin books, 1975, pp. 143-157.
  88. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late capitalism, op. cit., p. 231f. and p. 495.
  89. ^ Ernest Mandel, The economics of neocapitalism. Socialist Register 1964, pp. 56–67 [21]; André Gorz, Stratégie ouvriére et néocapitalisme, Paris: Le Seuil, 1964; Leo Michielsen, Neo-kapitalisme. Brussel: Jacquemotte Stichting, 1969.[22]
  90. ^ Paul Mattick, "Ernest Mandel’s 'Late Capitalism', in: Paul Mattick, Economic Crisis and Crisis Theory. London: Merlin Press, 1974.[23]; Chris Harman, "Mandel’s Late Capitalism". International Socialism, Vol. 2, number 1, July 1978, pp. 79ff;[24] Max Boddy, "The ICFI’s exposure of Ernest Mandel’s “neo-capitalism” and the analysis of the global economic crisis: 1967–1971". World Socialist Web Site, 8 September 2023.[25]
  91. ^ Ernest Mandel, A socialist strategy for Western Europe. London: Institute for workers' control, 1965.[26]
  92. ^ The Jameson Reader p. 165–166
  93. ^ Ernest Mandel, Le troisième âge du capitalisme. Paris: Editions 10/18 (Série Rouge), 1976; 2nd. ed. Éditions de la Passion, 1997.
  94. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late Capitalism. London: New Left Books, 1975, pp. 31-32.
  95. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late Capitalism. London: New Left Books, 1975, chapter 1.
  96. ^ Ernest Mandel, Long Waves of Capitalist Development – the Marxist Interpretation (2nd expanded edition). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995.
  97. ^ Ernest Mandel, "Het lange golven debat: de inzet". Vlaams Marxistisch Tijdschrift, Vol. 25, Issue 1, March 1991, pp. 7-17.[27]
  98. ^ See: Ernest Mandel, “Long waves, technological revolutions, and class-struggle cycles”, chapter 2 in Ernest Mandel, Long Waves of Capitalist development, 2nd edition. London: Verso, 1995, pp. 28-48; Ernest Mandel, "Theories of crisis : an explanation of the 1974-82 cycle", in: M. Gottdiener and Nicos Komninos (eds.), Capitalist development and crisis theory: accumulation, regulation and spatial restructuring. Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1989, pp. 30-58; Beverley Silver, "Class Struggle and Kondratieff Waves, 1870 to the Present". In: Alfred Kleinknecht, Ernest Mandel and Immanuel Wallerstein (eds.), New findings in long-wave research. Houndmills, UK: Macmillan Press, 1992pp. 279-296; Ismael Hossein-zadeh,”Long waves of capitalist development and the future of capitalism”. In: Ron Baiman,[28] Heather Boushey and Dawn Saunders (eds.), Political economy and contemporary capitalism. Armond, New York: M. E. Sharpe, 2000, pp. 78-84; Duncan Fraser, The political long-wave: the changing fortunes of the Left and the Right. Egham, Surrey: Lulu publications, 2013.
  99. ^ Ernest Mandel, The second slump. London: Verso, 1978; Ernest Mandel, Die Krise: Weltwirtschaft 1974-1986. Hamburg: Konkret Literatur Verlag, 1987.
  100. ^ See the Ernest Mandel bibliography by Wolfgang Lubitz, Petra Lubitz and others.
  101. ^ Ernest Mandel, "Why I am a Marxist". In: Gilbert Achcar (ed.), The legacy of Ernest Mandel. London: Verso, 1999, pp. 232-259.
  102. ^ The Jameson Reader, p. 216–217
  103. ^ Ernest Mandel, "Karl Marx", in: John Eatwell et al., The New Palgrave Marxian Economics. New York: W.W. Norton & Company, 1990, pp. 1-38.[29]
  104. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late Capitalism. London: New Left Books, 1975, p. 39, 42-43. See also: Ernest Mandel, "Partially independent variables and internal logic in classical Marxist economic analysis" in: Social Science Information (London), Volume 24, Issue 3, 1985, pp. 485-505. Reprinted in: Ulf Himmelstrand (ed.), Interfaces in economic & social analysis, London: Routledge, 1992, pp. 33-50.
  105. ^ Postmodernism, or, the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. 1991. pp. 438. ISBN 8190340328. OCLC 948832273.
  106. ^ David Harvey, The condition of postmodernity. An inquiry into the origins of cultural change. Oxford: Basical Blackwell, 1989, chapter 22.
  107. ^ The Jameson Reader, p. 190.
  108. ^ The Jameson Reader p. 164–171
  109. ^ London: newleftreview.org, June 2025
  110. ^ Corey Robin, “Waiting Game”, in: Sidecar newsletter, 20 June 2025.[30] Generally NLR/Verso Books does not acknowledge wikipedia sources. Geert Lovink, blogpost "Dare to Quote! On Zizek and Wikipedia". Institute of Network Cultures, Amsterdam University of Applied Sciences, 15 July 2010.[31]
  111. ^ Corey Robin’s website
  112. ^ Corey Robin biblio.
  113. ^ Ibid.
  114. ^ Ibid.
  115. ^ "According to Max Weber, ‘the spirit’ of capitalism [was] ‘the product of a long and arduous process of education’, a development continuing over centuries. Likewise, a socialist society is probably conceivable only as the outcome of a comprehensive process of education, a process in which social change is accompanied by self-change." — Marcel van der Linden (ed.), The Cambridge History of Socialism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2023, pp. 43-44.
  116. ^ The idea that "the workers are not yet ready" has a lengthy history in the Marxist tradition. See, for example, the debates with Karl Kautsky, Vladimir Lenin, Leon Trotsky, and Nikolai Bukharin in: Marcel van der Linden, Western Marxism and the Soviet Union. Leiden: Brill, 2007, chapter 2. An earlier example is a complaint by Karl Marx at a meeting of the Central Committee of the Communist League (15 September 1850): "While we tell the workers: you have to go through 15, 20, 50 years of civil war and people's struggles in order to change the conditions, to make yourselves ready to rule, instead it has been said: we must come to power immediately, or we can go to sleep." (Boris Nicolaievsky, "Towards a history of the Communist League, 1847-1852", in: International Review of Social History, Vol. 1 No. 2, August 1956, pp.234-252, at p. 243 and p. 249 [32]). Ernest Mandel liked to remind activists that "the biggest battles are still ahead of us, not behind us."
  117. ^ Dirk J. Struik (ed.), Birth of the Communist Manifesto. New York: International Publishers, 1971, p. 89.
  118. ^ Michael Perelman, Steal this idea. New York: Palgrave, 2002. Mariana Mazzucato, The Value of Everything: making and taking in the global economy. Allen Lane, 2018.
  119. ^ Ernest Mandel, "Why I am a Marxist". In: Gilbert Achcar (ed.), The legacy of Ernest Mandel. London: Verso, 1999.
  120. ^ Karl Marx, The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte (1852). Commentary: by Bob Jessop, The Political Scene and the Politics of Representation: Periodizing Class Struggle and the State in The Eighteenth Brumaire. Department of Sociology, Lancaster University (UK), December 2003, pp. 1-8, at pp. 7-8.[33]
  121. ^ Karl Marx, Theses on Feuerbach (1845, Thesis 3). See also: Ronald Francis Price, Marx and education in late capitalism. London/Sydney: Croom Helm, 1986, chapter 6, p. 107f.
  122. ^ Michele Dillon, Introduction to Sociological Theory (2009) p. 39.
  123. ^ M. Hardt/K. Weeks eds., The Jameson Reader (2000) p. 257

Further reading

edit