Uzawa's theorem, also known as the steady-state growth theorem, is a theorem in economic growth that identifies the necessary functional form of technological change for achieving a balanced growth path in the Solow–Swan and Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans growth models. It was proved by Japanese economist Hirofumi Uzawa in 1961.[1]

A general version of the theorem consists of two parts.[2][3] The first states that, under the normal assumptions of the Solow-Swan and Ramsey models, if capital, investment, consumption, and output are increasing at constant exponential rates, these rates must be equivalent. The second part asserts that, within such a balanced growth path, the production function, (where is technology, is capital, and is labor), can be rewritten such that technological change affects output solely as a scalar on labor (i.e. ) a property known as labor-augmenting or Harrod-neutral technological change.

Uzawa's theorem demonstrates a limitation of the Solow-Swan and Ramsey models. Imposing the assumption of balanced growth within such models requires that technological change be labor-augmenting. Conversely, a production function that cannot represent the effect of technology as a scalar augmentation of labor cannot produce a balanced growth path.[2]

Statement

edit

Throughout this page, a dot over a variable will denote its derivative concerning time (i.e.  ). Also, the growth rate of a variable   will be denoted  .

Uzawa's theorem

The following version is found in Acemoglu (2009) and adapted from Schlicht (2006):

Model with aggregate production function  , where   and   represents technology at time t (where   is an arbitrary subset of   for some natural number  ). Assume that   exhibits constant returns to scale in   and  . The growth in capital at time t is given by

 

where   is the depreciation rate and   is consumption at time t.

Suppose that population grows at a constant rate,  , and that there exists some time   such that for all  ,  ,  , and  . Then

1.  ; and

2. There exists a function   that is homogeneous of degree 1 in its two arguments such that, for any  , the aggregate production function can be represented as  , where   and  .

Sketch of proof

edit

Lemma 1

edit

For any constant  ,  .

Proof: Observe that for any  ,  . Therefore,  .

Proof of theorem

edit

We first show that the growth rate of investment   must equal the growth rate of capital   (i.e.  )

The resource constraint at time   implies

 

By definition of  ,   for all   . Therefore, the previous equation implies

 

for all  . The left-hand side is a constant, while the right-hand side grows at   (by Lemma 1). Therefore,   and thus

 .

From national income accounting for a closed economy, final goods in the economy must either be consumed or invested, thus for all  

 

Differentiating with respect to time yields

 

Dividing both sides by   yields

 
 

Since   and   are constants,   is a constant. Therefore, the growth rate of   is zero. By Lemma 1, it implies that

 

Similarly,  . Therefore,  .

Next we show that for any  , the production function can be represented as one with labor-augmenting technology.

The production function at time   is

 

The constant return to scale property of production (  is homogeneous of degree one in   and  ) implies that for any  , multiplying both sides of the previous equation by   yields

 

Note that   because  (refer to solution to differential equations for proof of this step). Thus, the above equation can be rewritten as

 

For any  , define

 

and

 

Combining the two equations yields

  for any  .

By construction,   is also homogeneous of degree one in its two arguments.

Moreover, by Lemma 1, the growth rate of   is given by

 .  

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ Uzawa, Hirofumi (Summer 1961). "Neutral Inventions and the Stability of Growth Equilibrium". The Review of Economic Studies. 28 (2): 117–124. doi:10.2307/2295709. JSTOR 2295709.
  2. ^ a b Jones, Charles I.; Scrimgeour, Dean (2008). "A New Proof of Uzawa's Steady-State Growth Theorem". Review of Economics and Statistics. 90 (1): 180–182. doi:10.1162/rest.90.1.180. S2CID 57568437.
  3. ^ Acemoglu, Daron (2009). Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. pp. 60-61. ISBN 978-0-691-13292-1.